ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW VOLUME 16 I NUMBER 3 | 2015 | ISSN 15800466 Deaccessioning and Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow in Manager s Hands: A Formal Model Andrej Srakar Analysis of the Effects of Introduction of an Additional Carbon Tax on the Slovenian Economy Considering Different Forms of Recycling Aleksandar Kešeljević, Matjaž Roman The Relevance of Employee-Related Ratios for Early Detection of Corporate Crises Mario Situm Science-Industry Cooperation in Slovenia: Determinants of Success Maja Bučar, Matija Roječ The Effect of HRM Quality on Trust and Team Cohesion Igor Ivašković E/B/R E/B/R Economic and Business Review is a refereed journal that aims to further the research and disseminate research results in the area of applied business studies. Submitted papers could be conceptual, interpretative or empirical studies. Literature reviews, conceptual frameworks and models that cover substantive insights are welcomed. Papers that employ either qualitative or quantitative research approaches, surveys, case studies, experiments or historical models can be considered for publication. It is expected that submitted articles contribute to increased understanding of the phenomenon studied and are efficiently written, methodologically clear, conceptually and empirically rigorous, readable and bias free. Authors need to highlight how the paper adds to domain kno wledge or improves existing knowledge in the area of applied business research. The topics covered by the journal include (alphabetically): Accounting and Auditing, Bank and Financial Management, Business Informatics, Business Logistics, Economics, Entrepre-neurship and small business management, International Business, Management, Marketing, Money and Finance, Tourism. Today's Economic and Business Review is the successor to the Economic Review (1950-1990), the Slovenian Economic Review (1991-1999) and the Economic and Business Review for Central and South-Easter n Europe (1999-2010). EDITORIAL BOARD Neven Borak, Jože Damijan, Mateja Drnovšek, Jurij Jaklič, Josef Konings, Igor Lončarski, Tj asa Redek, Vesna 2abkar Mary Amity, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, United States Adamantios Diamantopoulos, Universität Wien, Austria Tanja Dmitrović, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Polona Domadenik, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Jay Ebben, University of St. Thomas, United States Neil Garrod, University of Greenwich, United Kingdom Anja Geigenmüller, Technische Universität Bergakademie Freiberg, Germany Laszlo Halpern, Hungarian Academy of Sciences, Hungary Nevenka Hrovatin, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Robert Kaše, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Gayle Kerr, Queensland University of Technology, Australia Maja Makovec Brenčič, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Igor Masten, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Rasto Ovin, University of Maribor, Slovenia Daniel Örtqvist, Luleä University of Technology, Sweden Marko Pahor, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Danijel Pučko, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia John Romalis, University of Chicago, United States Friederike Schröder-Pander, VIerick Leuven Gent Management School, Belgium Christina Sichtmann, University of Vienna, Austria Sergeja Slapničar, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Beata Smarzynska Javorcik, Oxford University, United Kingdom Jan Svejnar, University of Michigan, United States Marjan Svetličič, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Miha Škeriavaj, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Bobekšuklev, University„St. Cyril and Methodius", Macedonia Janez Šušteršič, University of Primorska, Slovenia FitiTaki, University „St. Cyril and Methodius", Macedonia Bob Travica, University of Manitoba, Canada Peter Trkman, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Aljoša Valenti nčič, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Irena Vida, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia Joakim Wincent, Urnea University, Sweden Jelena Zorić, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia PUBLISHERS: THE REVIEW'S OFFICE: Faculty of Economics, Kardeljeva ploščad 17, SI-1001 Ljubljana, Slovenia. The review is co-financed by Slovenian Research Agency. URL: http://www.ebrjournal.net Economic and Business Review Faculty of Economics, Kardeljeva ploščad 17, SI-1001 Ljubljana, Slovenia tel: + 386 1 58 92 607, fax: + 386 1 58 92 698, email: ebr.editors<®ef.uni-lj.si Bound by Birografika Bori d.o.o., Ljubljana Printed by Copis d.o.o., Ljubljana Economic and Business Review is indexed in: Cabell's Directory of Open Access Journals Publishing Opportunities, DOAJ, Ebsco, Econlit, IBSS and ProQuest ISSN 1580-0466 e-ISSN 2335-4216 E/B/R Economic and Business Review is a refereed journal thai aims to further the research and disseminate research results in the area of applied business studies. Submitted papers could be conceptual, interpretative or empirical studies. Literature reviews, conceptual frameworks and models that cover substantive insights are welcomed. Papers that employ either qualitative or quantitative research approaches, surveys, case studies, experiments or historical models can be considered for publication. It is expected that submitted articles contribute to increased understanding of the phenomenon studied and are efficiently written, methodologically clear, conceptually and empirically rigorous, readable and bias free. Authors need to highlight how the paper adds to domain knowledge or improves existing knowledge in the area of applied business research. Vie topics covered by the journal include (alphabetically):Accounting and Auditing Bank and Financial Management, Business Informatics, Business Logistics, Economics, Entrepreneurship and small business management, International Business, Management, Marketing, Money and Finance, Tourism. AUTHORS GUIDELINES: 1. Prepare your manuscript as an MS Word or R TF document. 2. Check to be certain the final version of the manuscript is: • Prepared in accordance with the latest edition of the APA Publication Manual. • Single-spaced throughout, including tables, figures, quotes, headings, and references. • Formatted with a running head and page number in the upper right corner of each page. 3. Abstract: Include an abstract of no more than 100 words thai provides a brief and comprehensive summary of the articles contents (keep details to a minimum) as well as a good idea of the benefits to be gained from reading the article. Л. Keywords and classification: Include 5-7 keywords that accurately describe the manuscript's primary topic(s). Also include JEL (Journal of Economic Literature) Classification (http:// www.aeaweb.org/iournal/iel class svstem.php). please use no more than 2-3 descriptors. 5. Subdivision - numbered sections: Divide your article into clearly defined and numbered sections. Subsections should be numbered 1.1 (then 1.1.1,1.1.2,...), 1.2, etc. (the abstract is not included in numbering). Use this numbering also for internal cross-referencing: do not just refer to „the text". Any subsection may be given a brief heading. Each heading should appear on its own separate line. 6. Tables and figures: Number tables consecutively in accordance with their appearance in the text. Place footnotes to tables below the table body and indicate them with superscript lowercase letters. Avoid vertical rules. He sparing in the use of tables and ensure that the data presented in tables do not duplicate results described elsewhere in the article. 7. References: Citation in text. Please ensure that every reference cited in the text is also present in the reference list. All citations in the text should refer to: 1. Single author: the author's name (without initials, unless there is ambiguity) and the year of publication; 2. Two or three authors: all authors' names and the year of publication; 3. More authors: first author's name followed by „et al." and the year of publication. Citations may be made directly (or parenthetically). Groups of references should be listed first alphabetically, then chronologically. Examples: „as demonstrated (Allan, 1996a, 1996b, 1999; Allan & Jones, 1995). Kramer et al. (2000) have recently shown ...." Examples for reference list: References should be arranged first alphabetically and then further sorted chronologically if necessary. More than one reference from the same author(s) in the same year must be identified by the letters „а", „Ь", „с", etc., placed after the year of publication. Journal publication: Van der Geer, J., Hanraads, J.A.J. & Lupton, R.A. (2000). The art of writing a scientific article. Journal of the Sociological Communication, 163 (2), 51 -59. Book: Strunk Jr., W. & White, E.B. (1979). The Elements of Style (3rd ed.). New York: Macmillan. Chapter in an edited book: Mettam, G.R. & Adams, L..B. (1999). How to prepare an electronic version of your article. In Jones, B.S. & Smith , R.Z. (Eds.), Introduction to the Electronic Age (pp. 281 304). New York: E-Publishing. Web sites Factiva (2010). Dow Jones Reuters Business Interactive LLC. http://www.factiva.com (accessed June 5, 2010). E/B/R ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW CONTENTS 225 Andrej Srakar Deaccessioning and Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow in Manager's Hands: A Formal Model 247 Aleksandar Kešeljević Matjaž Koman Analysis of the Effects of Introduction of an Additional Carbon Tax on the Slovenian Economy Considering Different Forms of Recycling 279 Mario Situm The Relevance of Employee-Related Ratios for Early Detection of Corporate Crises 315 Maja Bučar Matija Rojec Science-Industry Cooperation in Slovenia: Determinants of Success 337 Igor Ivašković The Effect of HRM Quality on Trust and Team Cohesion DEACCESSIONING AND AGENCY COSTS OF FREE CASH FLOW IN MANAGER'S HANDS: A FORMAL MODEL1 ANDREJ SRAKAR2 Received: 9 February 2013 Accepted: 11 February 2015 ABSTRACT: The problem of agency costs of free cash flow in manager's hands has been firstly noted by Easterbrook and Jensen. We present one of the first attempts to formally model the problem in light of similar situation faced by managers of museums being allowed (or disallowed) to deaccession the artworks from their collections. We show that deaccessioning funds always lead to various forms of agency costs for the museum. This finding applies for any non-profit firm and its endowment. The task lying ahead is to formally prove the general conjecture also for the case of private for-profit firms. Keywords: deaccessioning, agency costs, free cash flow, principal-agent problem, non-profit firms JEL Classification: G32, L14, Z11 1. INTRODUCTION Deaccessioning is a problem which has been often discussed both in cultural economics as well as in the popular media and blogs, especially in recent years due to the rising economic crisis and attempts of deaccessioning the museum artworks by several American museums facing the crisis. Deaccessioning is sometimes proclaimed to be a possible panacea to financial problems of museums in economic crisis, as it still holds that museums have the larger part of their endowment in the form of artworks - highly valuable but also very often neglected and mostly unexhibited. So why shouldn't the museum's deaccession the redundant paintings, sculptures, photographs and other artworks in their collection if on the one hand they are left unused in the depos of the museums and on the other hand the museums are in dire need of additional financial resources? Some of the American museums (e.g. The Barnes Foundation, National Academy Museum, Brandeis University' Rose Art Museum) have tried to pursue the "deaccessioning path" yet have been mostly prevented by the rigorous action of the American Association of Museum Directors and American Association of Museums. 1 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: This research has been written with support from the Fulbright Scholarship Grant given to the author for the year 2011/12 and »Innovation scheme for financing of PhD studies, their cooperation with economy and solutions to societal challenges - generation 2010 University of Ljubljana« scholarship grant given to the corresponding author for the year 2010/11. The author thanks the Institute of International Education, School of Public and Environmental Affairs at Indiana University Bloomington and University of Ljubljana for their kind support. The author also thanks Prof. Michael J. Rushton and Prof. Liljana Ferbar Tratar for their great support during the research. 2 Institute for Economic Research, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: andrej.srakar@ier.si The question obviously entails both strong legal and moral problems (summarized by e.g. Fincham (2011) and Rohner (2010)). In this article we will prove that there exists another pervasive and dire problem of deaccessioning practices: they lead to non-optimal museum management. We will prove that allowing deaccessioning leads to incentives for managers to excessively use the deaccessioning funds and that they are therefore demoti-vated to raise the revenues of the museum in the presence of deaccessioning possibilities. Striking as this finding may appear, its message is simple and clear: allowing deaccession-ing to substitute for museum revenues in times of economic crisis (or in any time) leads not only to legal and moral issues, but also entails excess economic, i.e. agency costs. The case for deaccessioning therefore appears to lose ground and one would question if there is any strong and sensible argument in favor of deaccessioning left over. The article will be structured in the following way. The second section will provide a literature review and review of the most needed findings and concepts. In the third section we will present the model to be used for our purpose. In the fourth section we will present its solution and the main propositions for the case of risk-neutral principal. The proof of propositions for the risk-averse principal case will be presented in the fifth section. The final two sections will conclude with the discussion of the findings and their consequences. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Museums are a very special field of research in cultural economics, and they pose numerous microeconomic problems. These problems have been subject of research literature in past years. The research crystalized across several main topics: industrial organization of museums, superstar museums, charging for entrance to museums and deaccessioning practices. One of the main facts from the literature in museum management and economics is that museums have been subject to change in their main characteristics and most of all in the mission they serve: they have come to be customer-oriented, and their main task has become education and not simply preserving the dedicated objects anymore (Whitting-Looze, 2010). This change is being reflected in theoretical considerations as well, and substantial literature has grown in the fields of museum management and marketing. The phenomenon of superstar museums has been researched a lot, following the rise of big museums and their franchises (e.g. Guggenheim, Tate). The topic of superstar museums is being explored in cultural economics as well (e.g. Frey & Pommerehne, 1989; Frey, 2003). Charging for entrance to museums proved to be an extremely interesting topic for economists. According to welfare theoretical considerations, the appropriate charge for entrance should be zero, due to zero (or close to zero) marginal costs of every new entrant (Fernandez-Blanco & Prieto-Rodriguez, 2011). But the opinions vary because the fixed costs of museums should also be taken into consideration (as suggested by Frey & Meier, 2006) and most of all congestion costs should be accounted for, which accounts for marginal costs in the long run being possibly distinct from zero (Fernandez-Blanco & Prieto- Rodriguez, 2011). A new proposal for museum pricing has been made by Bruno Frey and Lasse Steiner (Frey & Steiner, 2010) which proposes that the fee is charged when leaving the museum according to the time spent there (the so-called pay-as-you-go principle). In the article we will explore another interesting and often quoted phenomena in the economics of museums, namely the deaccessioning practices, which denote "the permanent removal or disposal of an object from the collection of the museum by virtue of its sale, exchange, donation or transfer by any means to any person" (McKinney, in: Range, 2004). Deaccessioning has become a topic not only in US museums, but is also being considered in German, Dutch, French and UK museums and in other European states. Deaccessioning can of course be done in two most general ways: either the funds are spent to finance new collections which have been a common and mostly undisputed practice for decades, or the funds are spent to finance daily operation costs of a museum. It is the latter form that will be of interest in this article. Deaccessioning as a practice brought to light many controversies. In one of the first cultural economics' articles on this topic, J. M. Montias (1973) advocates for its usage: "If the Metropolitan resources are as depleted as Mr. Hoving (the director) makes them out to be, and if the exhibition space is fixed to the present wall capacities for the foreseeable future, then his decision - to sell essentially duplicate items to make room for paintings and sculptures that will fill serious gaps in the museum's collection - appears largely justified" (Montias, 1973). Later works often advocated for its usage as well (e.g. Weil, 1990; Borg, 1991). There has been and is to this day also a considerable opposition to deaccessioning in the museum world (Besterman, 1991, Cannon-Brookes, 1991). It has to be noted, first, that the subject is not well researched, especially in light of economic modeling of actual situations and problems it brings for museum management, and second, that it indeed brings controversies, which can be seen in the fierce debates in contemporary American intellectual and art scene (Rohner, 2010; Whitting-Looze, 2010; Fincham, 2011; Rosenbaum, 2009-2012; Zaretsky, 2009-2012; Munoz-Sarmiento, 2009-2012). Some basic reasons for the debate on deaccessioning have been summarized by O'Hagan (O'Hagan, 1998): 1) Many art museums have trustee status, which protects art works given in trust from being sold to satisfy creditors; however, by blocking the most efficient use and allocation of its available resources, donor restrictions can seriously hinder the attempt of museum trustees to keep the museum solvent; 2) Because collections demand space, protection, and maintenance, it seems sensible for the museum with precarious finances to deaccession artworks that are unable to be exhibited and unwanted; 3) Once allowing deaccessioning the politicians might insist on the sale of further works of art as the quid-pro-quo of further subsidy (although the opposite is more likely to apply, namely a large public outcry against the use of the money from the sale for anything other than the purchase of more art); 4) The issues concerning the process of deaccessioning: what conditions apply, who decides how it is to be disposed of, and how the proceeds are to be allocated. Finally, article by Di Gaetano and Mazza (2014) is one of the first to explore deaccession-ing from a formal modelling viewpoint. It explores the situation of deaccessioning from the viewpoint of donations (and donors) and uses tools from game theory to explore the situation of uncertainty about the museum's choice of deaccessioning. The authors' main results are that when deaccessioning is allowed, this may reduce private donations also to those museums which do not sale portion of their collections; and that a reduction in public grants may benefit museums committed not to deaccess, which contrasts with the common wisdom that budget cuts hurt especially museums that choose to discard the option of selling their collections. For our article, the key observation has been stated already by Montias: "The purpose of this discussion is to determine whether a rule barring the sale of major works would cause museum managers to accomplish their mission more efficaciously" (Montias, 1973). The problem of deaccessioning when considered in light of economics deals with questions of efficacy of museum management and with (appropriate) incentives posed to the managers. We will claim that when making decisions on deaccessioning, it is not only donors who are affected, but the managers of museums have strong incentives for non-optimal (from the principals and societal viewpoint) behavior and efficacy, as seen from either the level of effort or motivation to raise the revenues of the museum. We will evaluate this hypothesis in light of microeconomic theoretical models, formed on the basis of contract theory and modeling of principal-agent problem. The debate of principal-agent modeling has been started in the 1960's and 1970s with articles by Arrow (1963), Ross (1973) and Shavell (1979a; 1979b). The theory has been developed in works by Mir-rlees (1975); Grossman and Hart (1983; 1986) Holmström (1979), Holmström and Milgrom (1987), Laffont and Martimort (2002) and Bolton and Dewatripont (2006). Princip al-agent problem in most general summarizes the situation between one principal (e.g. person offering a contract) and one agent (e.g. person being offered a contract). Principal and agent most commonly have conflicting objectives and decentralized information which stress the importance of incentives in the relationship. The essential paradigm for the analysis of such behavior by economists is one where economic agents pursue, at least to some extent, their private interests. What is proposed by incentive theory is that this major assumption be maintained in the analysis of organizations, small markets, and any other kind of collective decision-making. In the principal-agent relationship the principal is therefore interested in performance of the firm and the proper incentives given to the agent so that the latter can provide the utmost level of effort to his task, while the agent is motivated by his payment and to provide the minimal amount of effort required (it is usually supposed that the agent has disutility of provided effort - the more effort he provides, the less satisfied he is, ceteris paribus). Certain main findings were provided already by the first researchers in the field. It has been often claimed that if one of the parties is risk-neutral (and the other risk-averse), this party should be "charged" with all the risk in the relationship meaning that the other (the risk-averse) party is being fully secured of its payment i.e. benefit. The latter is usually done by securing the risk-averse party a constant payoff with the risk-neutral party been given the residual rights of ownership (see: Grossman & Hart, 1986). In the economics of principal-agent problem (and contract theory in general) one can have perfect and symmetrical information in which case usually the problem can be provided with an immediate, sometimes trivial solution. Most commonly though one encounters problems of asymmetrical information, either in the form of adverse selection, when the principal or the agent doesn't know the other party's type (this can lead to signaling models, where the informed and unobserved party is providing the signals of his type to the uninformed one, or to screening models where the uninformed party is providing the signals to the informed one) or in the form of moral hazard, when one of the party (most commonly the principal) cannot observe the actions of the other. It has been shown that both problems lead to inefficient equlibria and second-best or sometimes even worse solutions of the model (see: Laffont & Martimort, 2002; Bolton & Dewatripont, 2006). A special subbranch of principal agent theory deals with agency costs of principal-agent relationship, most commonly related to financial theory. The main article is probably the contribution by Jensen & Meckling (1976) which started to talk about the concept of agency costs which could be attributed to monitoring expenditures by the principal, bonding costs of the agent and the residual loss (ibid.). Agency costs are therefore a special sort of transaction costs (being of course related to pioneering work of Coase and Williamson) which come out as a result of principal-agent relationship. A very special type of agency costs has been observed by Easterbrook (1984) and Jensen (1986): agency costs of free cash flow in hand of the managers of the firm. Jensen observes that free cash flow in the hands of the managers very often leads to poor management decisions either in the form of raising the perquisites of the managers beyond the optimal level or in the form of investing in project with negative net present value. Jensen sees debt as a device to discipline the managers in the presence of agency costs of this type (Jensen, 1986). Despite the thesis raising a lot of debate and econometric evidence (e.g. Crutchly & Hansen, 1989; Lang, Stulz & Walkling, 1991; Almeida, Campello & Weisbach, 2004; Fleming, Heaney & Mc-Cosker, 2005; Utami & Inanga, 2011) it has rarely been properly modeled and formally proved (for additional information see e.g. Tirole, 2006). More or less the only attempt to model the problem of agency costs of free cash flow and its relationship to debt in firms is the article by Grossman and Hart (1982)3. In this article the authors observe and prove that debt can serve the role of bonding device in the relationship of principal and agent/manager in a firm and that including debt can be in the manager's interest as it can serve to increase the value of the firm, which is also in manager's interest (ibid.). Grossman and Hart prove that level of debt is beneficial to the level of investment and firm's profits and market value. Several studies have explored the role of endowment and the economics and financing of non-profit firms in general. Papers by Hansmann (1980; 1990) and Fama and Jensen (1983a; 1983b) sketch some basic considerations regarding economics of non-profit organisations and role of non-profit endowments. First (lastingly more or less the only one so far) attempt on modeling the financial structure of non-profit organisations and their 3 The article was written before the Jensen's 1986 conjecture, therefore it does not address the Jensen's problem directly. agency structure have been made by Wedig and colleagues (Wedig et al., 1988; Wedig et al., 1996) on the case of non-profit hospitals. In their 1996's paper their evaluate role of tax-exempt debt in non-profit hospitals and show some important results (e.g. that non-profit firms behave as if they were following a target ratio of tax-exempt debt). Capital structure of non-profit organisations has been also analysed by Bowman (2002), who tests whether capital structure of non-profit firms could be better analysed by refering to pecking-order theory (which states that different forms of capital always follow the same order of attractiveness and usage) or instead to a static trade-off theory which is more in accordance with mentioned Jensen's conjecture. Bowman (and several other authors, e.g. Fisman & Hubbard, 2003) finds evidence for the latter. Among the other contributions that would have to mentioned are studies on capital structure of non-profit hospitals by Calem and Rizzo (1995) and Brickley and van Horn (2002), econometric evaluation of agency costs of excess endowments by Core, Guay and Verdi (2006) and economic model of non-profit entrepreneur behavior by Glaeser and Shleifer (2001). Finally, in an influential article, Fisman and Hubbard (2003) observe the role of endowment and its similarity to debt in the contributions of Jensen (1986) and Grossman and Hart (1982). The general conclusion, confirmed by econometric evidence is that excess endowments lead to significant agency costs in the sense of Jensen and Easterbrook. Yet this conclusion has been so far supported only by econometric evidence and rarely by any formal modeling, similar to evaluation of Jensen's (and Easterbrook's) conjecture in general. 3. MODEL In an important article in financial and principal-agent theory, Grossman and Hart (1982) show that debt can serve as a self-limitation device for a firm. Grossman and Hart analyze the model where there is no clearly defined principal and agent relationship - they are mainly interested in investment, its role in enhancing the market value of the firm and the impact on the expected utility function of the manager. On their account the manager optimizes the following function: where U is the managers utility function, у is the expected value of the firm, I is the investment itself, g(I) is the expected profit from the investment, d are current debt obligations and F is the cumulative density function. This formula therefore describes the manager's expected utility in the presence of the danger of bankruptcy due to debt obligations of the firm - the manager's expected utility depends upon the utility from current consumption V — I, which depends on the market value of the firm less the investment needed for changing the value of the firm. The manager's utility also depends upon the probability of solvency 1 — Fiji — g(0) which is modeled as probability that the current debt obligations D don't surpass in value the revenues of the firm g(I). The latter formula therefore measures the probability that the random variable s (which is defined as simply a random variable with mean 0) is greater than D — (total revenues are equal to g(0 plus this random variable) which is equivalent to solvency condition of the firm. We therefore propose to model the deaccessioning process in the following way. The budget function of the museum is: where R are total revenues of the museum, consisting of fundraising (including donations), ticket sales and public grants, w is wage of the manager and FC are remaining costs of the museum (including both fixed costs as well as costs depending upon the level of service, e.g. cleaning costs, costs of collection maintenance). RT denotes the difference between R and FC. We model possible role of deaccessioning as having a preventing function over possible bankruptcy of the museum, following the model by Grossman and Hart. If the museum should remain solvent, the following inequality has to be satisfied: where s is, again, a random variable with mean 0 and is simply denoting the random factors influencing the revenues of the museum and dE is the amount of endowment allowed for deaccessioning. Deaccessioning in this equation serves in the role of "reserve funds" available to prevent the possible bankruptcy of the museum (therefore if the budget is negative it has to be less in absolute value than the deaccessioning "reserve funds"). In our case, we use their model and extend it for a principal-agent situation. Our principal is the board of trustees of the museum, which hires the manager (the agent) to work for the benefit of the museum. Following Grossman and Hart, the following should be the specification of our principal-agent deaccessioning' problem in the risk-neutral principal case (if we assume that the main objective of the principal is the maximization of the expected budget in line with considerations of e.g. Niskanen, 1968; 1971): where RT — w is the net total budget, F is the cumulative distribution function, и is the managers utility function, ip is the manager s disutility from effort function and M is the minimal guaranteed level of manager's utility. The optimization problem is therefore to maximize the expected benefit of the principal (net revenues times the probability of no bankruptcy) such that the agent's expected utility is bigger than some guaranteed value. This problem doesn't include deaccessioning funds among revenues of the museum yet takes them into account in their role as a »buffer« against insolvency of the museum, in accordance with findings by Fisman and Hubbard (2003). The above discussion also shows two important considerations: 1) From the inequality (3) and from the model (4) & (5) we see that deaccessioning acts in exactly the opposite manner as debt in the model of Grossman and Hart. Is therefore serves as a sort of »negative debt«: as reserves that are a »buffer« against possible insolvency of the museum. 2) From the above it is also apparent that if we are able to prove that deaccessioning leads to non-optimal museum manager's/agent's decisions, this would be sufficient to show the Jensen's conjecture on agency costs of free cash flow in firms, if the free cash flow behaves in a similar manner as deaccessioning funds: it is not included in the budget function of the firm, yet can serve to cover the possible firm's insolvency. In the following we also make the following assumptions on marginal effects: dRT _ d2RT dw d2w ди d2u dip d2ip de de2 'de 'de2 < 0, —— > 0, dw я 2 0 dw* de dez ir4>o (6) We therefore assume that additional effort raises net non-labor revenues and that the net non-labor revenue function is concave in effort; that additional effort raises manager's wage and that the wage function is concave in effort; that the utility function of the manager is concave in wage; and that the manager's disutility function of effort is convex. All of the assumptions are common in principal-agent problems and will not be discussed here. In our propositions, we will explore two possible relationships between deaccessioning and effort. Firstly, deaccessioning will be assumed as fixed and independent of the level of provided effort. In this case, museum manager takes the level of deaccessioning as predetermined by rules of the museum. Second case if when deaccessioning can be left to vary and is dependent on the invested effort from the manager. It is logical to assume that the higher the provided effort, the lower will be the need for deaccessioning to act as a buffer to remedy for financial problems of the museum. 4. THE RISK-NEUTRAL PRINCIPAL CASE Solving the model leads to the following first order conditions and Lagrangian function: where we write F and и as short terms for F(w — RT — dE) and u(w). F.O.C.: dL — = -(1 - F) - (RT - w)f + foi'O - F) - Auf = 0 (8) uW where / is the probability density function of the distribution with cumulative distribution function F(w — RT — dE). Proposition 1: The constraint in (5) is binding or relying on funds from deaccessioning instead of on the raised revenues is optimal. Proof. We can express the value of \ from (8) as: (1 - F) + (RT ~w)f u'{l-F)-uf - (9) where the last inequality of course holds because A is the Lagrange multiplier and therefore non-negative. There are two possibilities: either Л — 0 or A > 0. In the first case, it should hold that: and therefore / 1 1 — F RT — w (11) Because 0 < /, F < 1, this would mean that the optimal value of the net revenues ( ) is negative which means that in this case relying on deaccessioning is optimal for the manager which contradicts the basic supposition of optimality of the behavior of the manager. This shows that in order for the manager to act optimally, the constraint in (5) should be binding (i.e. A > 0). Q.E.D. The F.O.C. over effort states that: Proposition 2: If the principal is risk-neutral and we make deaccessioning depend upon effort, the provided effort by the agent will be suboptimal. Proof. Let's firstly observe the case when deaccessioning is fixed and doesn't depend upon the effort in the model. By inserting the value of A from (9) into (12) we get: and finally after simplification: V/0) dR de u'( 1 - F) (14) ddE On the other hand, if deaccessioning depends upon effort (and we assume that ge <0, which simply means that higher effort, invested into work for the museum, leads to lower need to rely on deaccessioning, which seems a logical assumption), (12) transforms into: dL de (dRT\ (dRT\ (dd.E\ (dRT\ (ddE\ (-£) (1 ■- F) + ^- w) / + ffr w) (—) / + Я. (J) / + Ли (—) / - À-ф'Се) - 0 (15) which after inserting the value of of A from (9) can be simplified into: Again, some simplification yields: , a dE where the first inequality is due to negativity of (1 — fu'(Rr ~ w) (due to previ- ously made suppositions) and the second is due to positivity of u(w) in equilibrium - if it would be otherwise the signs of derivatives of (4) and (5) would be opposite and one would be able to increase (4) by going in the direction of its derivative while still being in the region of the constraint (5) which would contradict Proposition 1 that the constraint in (5) is binding. From (17) and due to positivity of (1 — F) + (Дт — w)f we are finally able to conclude: d2rt < 0 Comparing (14) and (18) and taking into account our initial supposition that~đe2 we conclude that the effort in (18) is lower than the effort in (14) which concludes our proof. Q.E.D. Let's shortly explain the intuition behind Proposition 2. Our main hypothesis of the article is that deaccessioning leads to worse performance of museum management. In Proposition 2 we therefore showed that if we allow effort to vary and have the influence on the level of deaccessioning funds (used as a buffer to remedy for financial problems of the museum), the invested effort will be lower than optimal (the marginal effect of effort to net revenues in equilibrium is higher when allowing deaccessioning to vary with effort and marginal effect of effort to net revenues is a monotonously decreasing function). This shows that usage of deaccessioning funds and invested effort are indeed inversely related and is the effect of including the (negative by assumption) marginal effect of effort to deaccessioning which has a negative marginal effect to derivatives of both (4) and (5) in the first order condition (15). In the following proposition we show another adverse effect of deaccessioning funds for performance of museum management. Proposition 3: In the risk-neutral principal' equilibrium the marginal effect of deaccessioning to wage is greater than the marginal effect of additional net revenues to wage. Also the marginal effect of deaccessioning to net revenues in the equlibrium is negative and greater than minus one. Proof.To calculate the marginal effect of deaccessioning over wage, we can use the second derivatives of the Lagrangian (using the implicit function theorem): Similarly we can calculate: dRT ddE d2L dwddE d2L (21) dwdRT The second order derivatives are: where the inequality holds because the Lagrangian is maximized at w, d2 X = -/ + (_RT - w)f + Au'f + Auf (23) - 2f I (RT w)f' I Xuf I Auf (24) dwddE d2L dwdRT From equations (20), (22) and (24) we have: and from equations (19), (22) and (23) we have similarly: Therefore: dw dw dR, + / ddE 2f + wf + Au"( 1 — F) — 2Xu'f - Auf' (27) Because of the inequality (22) the denominator in both (25) and (26) is strictly negative. This means that the last term on the right hand side of (27) is strictly negative (y - the probability density function - is of course strictly positive by assumption), which shows: This proves the first part of the proposition. The second part is shown similarly using (21), (23) and (24): dw 3w 8rt Now lets observe the signs of gdE, srt and gdE. It is natural to assume that the marginal effect of additional net revenues less wage to wage is positive otherwise the manager wouldn't be motivated for the benefit of the firm at all. Therefore it is natural to assume: From (28) we also gain: dw dw which means that the signs of both ^^ and ^r are positive. From equations (19) and (20) 32l and the fact that ^ is negative (as explained before) we gain: and therefore: But this means that deaccessioning funds have negative marginal effect on the total revenues, therefore on the success of the firm. This proves that allowing deaccessioning leads to decisions leading to lower revenues than optimal. This also proves our proposition. Q.E.D. Again, let's shortly explain the intuition behind Proposition 3. We showed that deaccessioning is more tempting for the manager not merely due to its adverse effect on effort (allowing managers to be more "lazy"), which we showed in Proposition 2, but also because it raises the manager's perquisites in the form of manager's wage, as claimed in the original article by Jensen (see Jensen, 1986). We, therefore, showed that the effect of deaccession-ing on the level of equilibrium wage is higher than the effect of revenues to equilibrium wage which clearly demonstrates adverse effect of deaccessioning to manager's perquisites (deaccessioning funds are more tempting for the manager than raising of the revenues because he secures higher wage by using deaccessioning). Furthemore, we showed that deaccessioning and net revenues are negatively related also when observed in a direct relationship. 5. THE RISK-AVERSE PRINCIPAL CASE We next observe our model in the case of principal being risk-averse and prove the validity of our two main propositions also for this case. In this case, the model in (4) and (5) changes to: where B(RT — w) (we will write it shortly as В) is the benefit function of the principal and we assume B' > 0,5" < 0. Solving the model in (34) and (35) leads to the following Lagrangian function: The first order conditions over wage and effort are: d£ — = —B'(l -F)-Bf + Äu'[ 1 - F] - Xuf = 0 dw (37) dL fdRj ®(i-/7)+4lr)/+Шf- =0 (38) From (37) we get: B'(l -F) + Bf A = —----- > 0 u'(l-F)-uf~ (39) Again, due to В' > 0 we see that for À = 0 (i.e. constraint in (35) to be non-binding), would have to be negative in equilibrium and relying on deaccessioning would be an optimal strategy. We next prove our Propositions 2 and 3 also in the case of risk-averse principal. Proposition 4: If the principal is risk-averse and we make deaccessioning depend upon effort, the provided effort by the agent will be suboptimal. Proof. Again, firstly observe the case when deaccessioning is fixed and doesn't depend upon the effort in the model. By inserting the value of Ä from (39) into (38) we get: and finally after simplification: dR7 Ф'(е) de u'(l - F) (40) ddE On the other hand, if deaccessioning depends upon effort (again, we assume that ~^T<0), (38) transforms into: dl _ B,fdRT de V de = 0 \ fdRT\ !ddE\ fdRT\ (ddE\ V(1-F>+B Ье-)-f + B Ы 'f + Ы behf+ ÀU beif " ^ (41) which after inserting the value of of Ä from (39) can be simplified into: Again, some additional simplification yields: where the final inequality is due to term B'u + Bu' being positive, as B1 and u' are positive by initial assumptions, В is positive by previous reasoning at the start of this section, and и is positive by the same reasoning as in proof of Proposition 2. From (43) it is easily deduced that: Ч- VO) > (44) de u'( 1 - F) Again, Comparing (40) and (44) and taking into account our initial supposition that 32Rt < n de2 ~ , we conclude that the effort in (44) is lower than the effort in (40) which concludes our proof. Q.E.D. Proposition 5: Proposition 3 holds also in the case of risk-neutral principal with the additional assumption л 1 — F = г > В" В7 = ARA (45) Proof. The inequality in (45) can be interpreted in the following way. According to Pratt (1964), the Arrow-Pratt coefficient of absolute risk aversion (ARA) can be interpreted as willingness-to-pay the insurance (risk premium), i.e. willingness-to-pay to avoid risk. On the other hand as interpreted by Grossman and Hart (1982) the hazard rate (r) in the model described by equation (1) can be interpreted as marginal cost of avoiding bankruptcy, therefore marginal cost of avoiding risk in our model. Inequality (45) therefore only means that the principal's willingness to pay the risk premium to avoid risk is smaller than the cost of avoiding risk, which is a necessary condition for the principal to be willing to take the risk of bankruptcy and therefore to participate in the game described by the model (34) and (35). Inequality (45) is therefore nothing else than the participation condition for the principal. Calculating the second order derivatives and implicit function quotients in this case gives: - B"(l -F) + 2B'f - Bf + Au"( 1 - F) - 2Àu'f - Àuf < 0 (46) = -B'f + Bf' + Àu'f + Àuf (47) = B"( 1 F) 2 B'f + Bf + Àu'f + Лuf (48) dw2 d2L dwddE d2L dwdR dw dw + - B"(l - F) + B'f dRT ddE B"(l-F) + 2B'f-Bf +Àu"(l - F) - 2Àu'f-Àuf Because of inequality (45) it holds: B"(l — F) + B'f> 0 (52) And therefore again (as in the risk-neutral principal case) it holds: (51) All the other steps in proving the analogue of proposition 3 are the same. Q.E.D. 6. DISCUSSION It is apparent that we just showed several adverse effects of allowing deaccessioning funds. Firstly, deaccessioning has negative effects on the effort of the managers in equilibrium - managers will tend to work less in the presence of deaccessioning funds, being able to cover for the possible deficit of the museum, if we allow their effort to provide funds for the museum which could lower the need for deaccessioning. This finding was demonstrated in Propositions 2 and 4 for both risk-neutral as well as risk-averse case. Secondly, using deaccessioning funds is more tempting for the manager than raising revenues. This shows that in the presence of deaccessioning the manager has less motivation to work for the benefit of the museum, but will be more tempted to rely on deaccessioning funds, leaving the work for the benefit of the museum (i.e. raising revenues of the museum) for others to come. This is finally and once more confirmed by the negative sign of marginal effect of deaccessioning to the revenues - the more we allow deaccessioning possibilities to cover the possible deficit of the museum, the lower will be the total revenues. One would be tempted of course to generalize this finding to behavior of managers in non-profit as well as for-profit firms. For the non-profit firms the result is immediate: allowing firms to rely on endowment funds for covering their possible deficit is economically detrimental to the incentives of a non-profit firm. This goes in line with the econometric findings in the literature (e.g. Fisman & Hubbard, 2003; Core, Guay & Verdi, 2006) yet goes of course a step further by formally proving the detrimental effects of large endowment funds for the incentives in non-profit firms. So how about the for-profit firms? In Section 2 we presented the conjecture by Jensen and Easterbrook which says that excess free cash flow in hands of the managers entails agency costs in the form of excessive perquisites and investments in negative net present value projects. We are unfortunately at this point not able to prove that free cash flow acts exactly like deaccessioning (and/or endowment) funds in non-profit firms. We hadn't addressed all the different forms of negative effects of deaccessioning: do they lead to more perquisites on the side of managers (that appears to be the case) or do they lead to investments in negative net-present value projects, or perhaps even both? To account for this one would need to have a more specified basic model, including separate measures for all these effects. Yet we are able to say that if the free cash flow in for-profit firms acts in a manner as deaccessioning funds in our case, therefore if it is not included among the firm-value raising funds, yet could be spent to finance the possible deficit of the firm, then we are able to formally show (and have shown in this article) that this leads to adverse effects in terms of the agency costs. 7. EXTENSIONS OF THE MODEL The model describes the situation in which there is a clearly specified relationship between principal and agent. In this way it improves on the model of Grossman and Hart who only use the optimization for the agent. Yet we specify manager's utility only in terms of his expected benefits from wage and disutility from effort. One could of course follow Grossman and Hart's logic further in specifying that the manager's utility depends also on bonding actions and value of the museum. In this way one would have to include in the manager's utility function also the utility from the value of museum (its revenues and most of all its endowment). As Grossman and Hart clearly state, the firm's market value is in the manager's own interest and therefore his utility function could (or should) be made dependent on the value of the museum. This would complicate the model further, yet would be more in line with original model and findings by Grossman and Hart. Secondly, an apparent extension of the model would be to include the possibility of asymmetric information. One would expect that in the presence of deaccessioning, moral hazard problems would be extended and managers would tend to shirk to the expense of the principals and museum in general. There are many other extensions that could be made to the specification of the principal-agent problem in our model. One could firstly argue about the choice of principal and agent. In one of the rare existing articles on principal-agent modeling in cultural economics Prieto-Rodriguez and Fernandez-Blanco (2006) consider the public agency (providing subsidies) to be the principal and the museum (or its board) to be the agent in museum financing decisions. One could also argue that museum has multiple principals: both the board of trustees as well as the donors can serve the role of principals. It would be interesting to include multiple principals (or even multiple agents) in our principal-agent problem following work of e.g. Bernheim & Whinston (1986), Li (1993), Martimort (1996), Waterman & Meier (1998) and Gailmard (2002), taking into account the externalities of one principal-agent relation for another principal-agent relation. One could furthermore argue that museums follow versatile objectives beside revenue maximization and are motivated by educational, aesthetic and other purposes as well. To this task, the extensions following Holmström and Milgrom's 1991 multitasking model would be most appropriate. One could also speculate that principal can follow a more general utility function and is not risk neutral as presupposed in our article. Yet we consider this observation would change nothing in the results of this paper which is demonstrated in the appendix. One further extension of course concerns econometric evidence. Unfortunately the data on deaccessioning are not available presently in 990' non-profit organizations' forms, therefore an econometric study would be of only limited scope. One could of course try to gather the data by using questionnaires sent to museums. Still we consider that deacces-sioning is considered as "barely legal" practice in American (and even more-so in other) museums, therefore the answers to questionnaires would be probably prone to a large non-response bias. Nevertheless, one would be able to show that excess endowment of museums in general contributes adversely to the benefit of the museum and positively to the perquisites of museum managers. Another extension considers the solutions to the problems shown in the model. We were able to show the negative effects of deaccessioning to the incentives for managers in mu- seums. One would be obliged to further explore if (and how) this problem could be prevented and if there is any mechanism to reduce the agency costs of allowing for deaccessioning. One would be tempted to use the literature in mechanism design theory to resolve this problem. Finally, the proof in our article is still insufficient to prove the Jensen's agency costs of free cash flow conjecture for the case of for-profit firms. This question, therefore, remains open for future research, yet we believe the methods in our article should provide sufficient research directions for final solution to this problem in financial theory and theory of the firm. REFERENCES Almeida, H., Campello, M. & Weisbach, M.S. (2004). The Cash Flow Sensitivity of Cash. The Journal of Finance, 59(4), 1777-1804. Arrow, K.J. (1963). Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care. The American Economic Review, 53(5), 941-973. Bernheim, B.D. & Whinston, M.D. (1986). Common Agency. Econometrica, 54(4), 923-942. Besterman, T. (1991). The Ethics of Emasculation. Museums Journal, 91, 25-28. Bolton, P. & Dewatripont, M. (2006). Contract Theory. Cambridge, London: MIT Press. Borg, A. (1991). Confronting Disposal. Museums Journal, 91, 29-31. Bowman, W. (2002). The Uniqueness of Nonprofit Finance and the Decision to Borrow. Nonprofit Management & Leadership, 12(3), 293-311. Brickley, J.A. & van Horn, R.L. (2002). Managerial Incentives in Nonprofit Organizations: Evidence from Hospitals. Journal of Law and Economics, XLV, 227-249. Calem, P.S. & Rizzo, J.A. (1995). Financing Constraints and Investment: New Evidence from Hospital Industry Data. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27(4), 1002-1014. Cannon-Brookes, P. (1996). Cultural-Economics Analyses of Art Museums: a British Curator's Viewpoint. In Ginsburgh, V.A., Menger, P.-M. (Eds.), Economics of the Arts - Selected Essays (pp. 255-274). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Core, J.E., Guay, W.R. & Verdi, R.S. (2006). Agency problems of excess endowment holdings in not-for-profit firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 41, 307-333 Crutchly, C. & Hansen, R. (1989). A test of the agency theory of managerial ownership, corporate leverage and corporate dividends. Financial Management, 18, 36-76. Di Gaetano, L. & Mazza, I. (2014). Better an egg today than a hen tomorrow: On the implications of deaccesspolicies on donations to museums. ACEI Working Paper Series AWP-01-2014, Association for Cultural Economics International Easterbrook, F. (1984). Two Agency Cost Explanations of Dividends. American Economic Review, 74, 650-659. Fama, E.F. & Jensen, M.C. (1983a). Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 301-325. Fama, E.F. & Jensen, M.C. (1983b). Agency Problems and Residual Claims. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), 327-349. Feldstein, M. (1991). Introduction. In Feldstein, M. (Ed.) The Economics of Art Museums (pp. 1-12). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Fernandez-Blanco, V. & Prieto-Rodriguez, J. (2011). Museums. In Towse, R. (Ed.), Handbook of Cultural Economics (2nd ed., pp. 290-296). Cheltenham, Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing. Fincham, D. (2011). Deaccession of Art from the Public Trust. Art Antiquity and Law, 16(2), 1-37. Fisman, R. & Hubbard, R.G. (2003). The Role of Nonprofit Endowments. In Glaeser, E.L. (Ed.), The Governance of Not-for-Profit Organizations (pp. 217-234). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Fleming, G., Heaney, R. & McCosker, R. (2005). Agency Costs and Ownership Structure in Australia. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 13, 29-52. Frey, B.S. (2003). Arts & Economics. Analysis & Cultural Policy. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York: Springer-Verlag. Frey, B.S. & Pommerehne, W.W. (1989). Muses and Markets: Explorations in the Economics of the Arts. Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Frey, B.S. & Meier, S. (2006). The Economics of Museums. In Ginsburgh, V.A., Throsby, C.D. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture (pp. 1017-1047). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Frey, B.S. & Steiner, L. (2010). Pay as you go: A new proposal for museum pricing. Copenhagen: 16th Conference of Association for Cultural Economics International, Mimeo. Gailmard, S. (2002). Multiple Principals and Outside Information in Bureaucratic Policy Making. Mimeo, Irving B. Harris Graduate School of Public Policy Studies, University of Chicago. Glaeser, E.L. & Shleifer, A. (2001). Not-for-profit entrepreneurs. Journal of Public Economics, 81(2001), 99-115. Grossman, S.J. & Hart, O.D. (1982). Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives. In McCall, J.J. (Ed.), The Economics of Information and Uncertainty (pp. 107-140). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Grossman, S.J. & Hart, O.D. (1983). An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem. Econometrica, 51(1), 7-45. Grossman, S.J. & Hart, O.D. (1986). The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691-719. Hansmann, H.B. (1980). The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise. The Yale Law Journal, 89(5), 835-901. Hansmann, H.B. (1990). Why Do Universities Have Endowments? The Journal of Legal Studies, 19(1), 3-42. Holmström, B. (1979). Moral Hazard and Observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 74-91. Holmström, B. & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and Linearity in the Provision of Intertemporal Incentives. Econometrica, 55, 303-28. Holmström, B. & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 7, 24-52. Jensen, M.C. (1986). Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76(2), 323-329. Jensen, M.C. & Meckling, W.H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360. Laffont, J.-J. & Martimort, D. (2002). The theory of incentives: the principal-agent model. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Lang, L.H.P., Stulz, R.M. & Walkling, R.A. (1991). A test of the free cash flow hypothesis. The case of bidder returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 29), 315-335. Li, S. (1993). Competitive Matching Equlibrium and Multiple Principal-Agent Models. Center for Economic Research, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota: Discussion Paper No. 267, January 1993. Martimort, D. (1996). Exclusive Dealing, Common Agency, and Multiprincipals Incentive Theory. RAND Journal of Economics, 27, 1-3l. Mirrlees, J.A. (1975, reprinted 1999). The Theory of Moral Hazard and Unobservable Behaviour, Part 1. Review of Economic Studies, 66(1999), 3-21. Montias, J.M. (1973, reprinted 1995). Are Museums Betraying the Public's Trust. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19, 71-80. Munoz-Sarmiento, S. (2009-2012). Articles on »The Deaccessioning Blog«, http://clancco-theartdeaccessioning-blog.blogspot.com/ (accessed February 9, 2013). Niskanen, W. A. (1968). The Peculiar Economics of Bureaucracy. American Economic Review, 58(2), 293-305. Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton. O'Hagan, J. (1998). Art Museums: Collections, Deaccessioning and Donations. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22, 197-207. Pratt, J.W. (1964). Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large. Econometrica, 32(1/2), 122-136. Prieto-Rodriguez, J. & Fernandez-Blanco, V. (2006). Optimal pricing and grant policies for museums. Journal of Cultural Economics, 30, 169-181. Range, D. (2004). Deaccessioning and Its Costs in the Holocaust Art Context: The United States and Great Britain. Texas International Law Journal, 39, 655-674. Rohner, J.L. (2010). Profiting from paintings and paying the price: the implications of increased deaccessioning for general operating expenses in U.S. art museums. Master of Arts Thesis, Faculty of Teachers College, Columbia University. Rosenbaum, L. (2009-2012). Articles on »CultureGrrl Blog«, http://www.artsjournal.com/culturegrrl/ (accessed February 9, 2013). Ross, S. (1973). The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem. American Economic Review, 63, 134139. Shavell, S. (1979a). On Moral Hazard and Insurance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 541-62. Shavell, S. (1979b). Risk-Sharing and Incentives in the Principal and Agent Relationship. Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 55-73. Tirole, J. (2006). The Theory of Corporate Finance. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Utami, S.R. & Inanga, E.L. (2011). Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Dividend Policy, and Leverage of Firms in Indonesia. European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences, 33(2011), 7-24. Waterman, R.W. & Meier, K. (1998). Principal-Agent Models: An Expansion? Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 8, 173-202. Wedig, G., Sloan, F.A., Hassan, M. & Morrissey, M.A. (1988). Capital Structure, Ownership, and Capital Payment Policy: The Case of Hospitals. The Journal of Finance, 43(1), 21-40. Wedig, G., Hassan, M. & Morrissey, M.A. (1996). Tax-Exempt Debt and the Capital Structure of Nonprofit Organizations: An Application to Hospitals. The Journal of Finance, 51(4), 1247-1283. Weil, S. (1990). Rethinking the Museum: And Other Meditations. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution Press. Whitting-Looze, B.M. (2010). Collections as communication: deaccessioning policies and public trust. Masters of Science Thesis, University of Oregon. Zaretsky, D. (2009-12). Articles on »The Art Law Blog«, http://theartlawblog.blogspot.com/ (accessed February 9, 2013). ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION OF AN ADDITIONAL CARBON TAX ON THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY CONSIDERING DIFFERENT FORMS OF RECYCLING1 ALEKSANDAR KEŠELJEVIĆ2 Received: 29 April 2013 MATJAŽ KOMAN3 Accepted: 14 November 2014 ABSTRACT: This paper outlines some of the environmental and economic implications of an additional CO2 tax of EUR 15/tCO2 in Slovenia in the period 2012-2030 in order to determine whether it yield a double dividend. Authors analyze (using E3ME model) different forms of revenue recycling by reducing the social security contributions of either the employers or the employees or by reducing the public deficit, in order to identify the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental and economic welfare (double dividend). In this policy orientated paper authors argue that a reduction of employee social security contributions has more favourable effect than a reduction in employers' social security contributions. Keywords: green tax, environmental tax reform, double dividend, carbon tax, recycling, E3ME model JEL Classification: E17, H23, Q50 1. INTRODUCTION - GREEN TAXES AND ENVIRONMENTAL TAX REFORM (ETR) The idea of a green tax dates back to Arthur C. Pigou (1920); hence, green tax is also referred to as a Pigouvian tax. It is based upon a fundamental principle that the polluters should pay a tax in the amount equal to the damages resulting from their impact on the environment (i.e. negative externalities). The costs are namely not incurred only by the company whose emissions pollute the environment; rather, the costs are sustained by the entire society. It is then the task of the government to impose the green tax to internalize the pollution costs as much as possible. In such case, the polluting industrial activity is reduced to a socially desirable level (Turner, 1994). Introduction of the green tax represents also an important development in the public finance reform since it involves also a reconsideration of the present tax system, aimed 1 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: Kešeljević's and Koman's research in this paper was supported by grant No V5-1004 of the Slovenian Research Agency (ARRS) and the Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development (UMAR). The authors would like to thank Katarina Ivas from Insitute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development and people from Cambridge Econometrics, specially Eva Alexandri, for helpful comments and suggestions. 2 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Economics, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: saso.keseljevic@ef.uni-lj.si 3 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Economics, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: matjaz.koman@ef.uni-lj.si predominantly at taxing labour and capital. The environmental tax reform (ETR) argues in favour of green taxes in a revenue-neutral fashion to reduce other distortionary levies. Instead of taxing "good things" like labour, income and capital, the government should start taxing "bad things" like pollution, use of natural resources etc. (Bousqet, 2000; Pat-uelli et al., 2005). The main goal of an environmental tax reform is therefore an improvement in both environmental (first dividend) and economical aspects (second dividend). Environmental dividend involves reduction in emissions and economic dividend stems from lower costs, improved competitiveness, and higher employment. Therefore, the term "double dividend" is increasingly used to describe the environmental tax reform (Glomm et al., 2008; Ekins, 2009). Experience from European countries has shown, that effects of a comprehensive ETR have been positive in most cases (Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands, UK, Finland, Norway, Germany). Therefore, the environmental tax reforms (ETR) have become a relevant instrument in the economic policies of the developed world in recent years. Our primary goal is to determine the effect of an additional carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2 i.e. EUR 55 per ton of carbon) in the period 2012-2030 on the Slovenian economy, in order to determine whether an additional carbon tax would indeed yield a double dividend. We shall examine the possibilities of different recycling options either through reduction of budget deficit or reduction of employer/employee social security contributions, in the form of different scenarios (using E3ME model) in order to identify the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental (first dividend) and economic welfare (second dividend). The article is structured as follows. In section two the concept of double dividend is introduced. In section three we present the E3ME model and the impact of green taxes within the model. Results regarding the environmental and economic implications of an environmental tax reform are presented in section four. Finally, the last section deals with the conclusions and policy implications derived from the contents of the paper. 2. A DOUBLE DIVIDEND The two central dilemmas regarding the green tax have to do with regressiveness and loss of competitiveness. Many authors have argued that incidence of green taxes falls largely on the low-income class (Roed, 2006; West, Williams, 2004; Labandeira, Labeaga, 1999; Tiezzi, 2001; Clinch et al., 2006). Negative effect on cost competitiveness of the economy will be greater when (1) elasticity of demand for a certain good is relatively high; (2) there is strong competition in the industry; (3) a particular sector is highly energy-intensive; (4) ecotax is introduced in a small number of countries; and (5) there is no option to substitute the polluting activity with an environmentally friendlier technology (Kosonen, Nicodème, 2009; Clinch et al., 2006; Patuelli et al., 2005; Baron, 1997; Envoldsen et al., 2009). Thus, if the government introduces ETR without recycling the tax revenue within the system, an economic downturn would likely occur. Recycling in this case refers to targeted use of green tax revenue, especially for reducing the taxation of labour and social security contributions. Besides a reduction of social security contributions or personal income taxes, other forms of financial recycling are also possible by transfers to households/industries for greater energy efficiency4 or interventions in corporate income taxes and value added tax. In case of total recycling, the total tax burden remains unchanged (fiscal neutrality) (Speck, Jilkova, 2009; Ludewig et al., 2010; OECD, 2007; Hoerner, Bosquet, 2001; Clinch et al., 2006; Patuelli et al., 2005; Hansen, Holger, 2000). We expect an environmental tax reform to lead to an improvement from environmental aspects, e.g. owing to lower carbon dioxide emissions, as well as to improve the cost competitiveness of the economy as a result of lower labour costs and higher technological efficiency of businesses. Hence, economic growth and employment will actually increase (Benoit, 2000; Hoerner et al., 2001; Patuelli et al., 2005; Tuladhar, Wilcoxen, 1999). Not surprisingly, the European countries with the highest tax on labour were the first to implement the environmental tax reform and look for double dividend (Finland, Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands, Germany, and Norway). The first (environmental) dividend of the double dividend hypothesis is widely accepted. Johansson (2000) argues that in Sweden the CO2 emissions were 15% lower than they would have been in the absence of the green taxes. Berkhout and Linderhof (2001) point out that in the Netherlands, the price of electricity and fuel for domestic use rose dramatically as a result of the green tax and ex-post studies show that consumers now use 15% less electricity and 5-10% less fuel. Baron (1997) pointed out that in Denmark recycling of tax revenues through investment in energy efficiency has led to about 4.7% reduction in CO2 emissions. Labandeira et al. (2004) show that in Spain a tax on CO2 emissions has resulted in environmental improvement. Ludewig et al. (2010) demonstrate that use of all motor fuels in Germany was decreasing in the period from 1995 to 2006 by an average rate of 0.3 percent per year. At the same time, use of public transport was rising. Based on an analysis of 139 simulation models, Bosquet (2000) found that a considerable drop in carbon dioxide emissions is among the expected effects of a green tax reform in the short to medium run. The second (economic) dividend depends mainly on the structure of the economy (e.g. labour market, pre-existing tax structure), time lag and explicit model assumptions. Since the present tax system creates significant disincentives to work and hire, virtually any environmental policy can compound these existing distortions (Carraro et al., 1996; Morgenstern, 1995; Tuladhar, Wilcoxen, 1999; Schob, 2003). Ludewig et al. (2010) find that 250,000 new jobs were created in Germany in this way. Experience from Denmark (Hansen, Holger, 2000) and Spain (Manresa, Ferran 2005) is similar. However, many authors argue that the "double dividend" theory oversimplifies a number of points and that certain conditions have to be fulfilled for a double dividend. 4 Alternative recycling method are: (1) improvements in the energy efficiency of the building stock, (2) grants for improving energy efficiency in buildings, (3) recycling into local environmental projects to foster community acceptance of ETR, (4) recycling to public transport, (5) subsidising renewable energy and combined heat and power production, (6) subsidising 'cleaner' technology in industry, (7) subsidising R&D (Clinch et al., 2006). Firstly, ETR is expected to improve the quality of the environment and to reduce the distortions of existing taxes. This view has been questioned in several papers (Goulder, 1995; Benoit, 2000; De Mooij, 1999; Li, Ren, 2012). The basic point is that the double dividend hypothesis ignores the interaction between environmental taxes and pre-existing tax structure. If the initial tax system is suboptimal then ETR can generate a significant double dividend. Similarly Fraser and Waschik (2013) using a CGE model to empirically examine the double dividend hypothesis provide support for the existence of a strong double dividend when revenue is recycled through reductions especially in consumption taxes. Secondly, the outcome depends very much on labour market conditions in the country (Clinch et al., 2006; Carraro et al., 1996; Schob, 2003; Koskela and Schob, 1999; Holmlund and Kolm, 2000; Albrecht, 2006; Ciaschini et al., 2012). If there are labour rigidities (as in some countries of Europe), then there will be an employment dividend resulting from the recycled carbon tax revenue. But in the long run, such rigidities become less relevant. Thirdly, green taxes represent, as a rule, a relatively small share of overall tax revenue of any given country5. Hence, a dramatic increase would be required to offset the lower personal income tax revenue. Thus, if green taxes are set high enough to achieve meaningful reductions in emissions, they may cause significant distortions in the tax system. Policy makers will then be forced to trade off cleaner environment against other policy targets (Coxhead, 2000). Fourthly, Carraro et al (1996) find that the unions' negotiating strength affects the possibility of gains in employment. In the short run the employment may increase due to lower taxes; however, in the long run, net wages completely absorb the tax change, thus bringing employment back to its baseline value. Many authors argue that the effects of a green tax reform are doubtful in the long run. Nevertheless, while the second dividend may be in doubt, the first dividend remains a powerful argument for the introduction of ETR. Obviously, a strong double dividend occurs under rather "constrained" circumstances. We do not go more into the details since the rise and fall of the double dividend hypothesis and conditions for it has been discussed at length elsewhere (Bovenberg and Goulder 1997; Parry and Oates, 1998; Goulder, 1995; Bosquet, 2000; Fraser and Waschik, 2013). All authors agree that validity of the doubledividend hypothesis cannot be settled as a general matter. In other words, each reform must be evaluated on its own merits by keeping in mind the characteristics of respective countries and the explicit model assumptions. 5 In most EU countries, revenue from green taxes is between 2% and 3% of GDP. There are only four EU countries where such share in lower than 2% (1.9% in Slovakia, 1.9% in Lithuania, 1.6% in Spain, 1.8% in France), and only three countries where this share exceeds 3.5% of GDP (4% in Denmark, 4% in the Netherlands, 3.6% in Slovenia). Green taxes represent the largest share of total tax revenue in Bulgaria (10.7%), the Netherlands (10.3%), and Slovenia (9.6%). The lowest contribution of green taxes to overall tax revenue was observed in France (4.2%), Belgium (4.7%), and Spain (5.2%). Slovenia is considerably above the EU27 average (6.2%) with its 9.6-percent share of green tax revenue in overall tax revenue (European Commission, 2012). 3. THE MODEL There are two different methodological approaches to modelling the relation between the environment and the rest of the economy. The first approach is based on highly precise modelling of a certain sector; as a rule, however, such models do not yield the best explanations as to the interaction between the sector at hand and the economy as a whole. The other approach is based on structural macroeconomic models. A key advantage of these models, each of them is based on certain underlying assumptions, is that they allow a fairly accurate prediction of macroeconomic results in case of different scenarios. These models provide a better understanding of the economic consequences of environmental measures as they allow studying the economic processes that lead to final results. The downside of these models is that each sector is modelled at the aggregated level6. Our analysis is based on the latter approach. We employed the E3ME7 model, widely used among European researchers in recent years. This is a dynamic simulation econometric model intended for analysis of the effects of E3 policies (economy, energy, environment), especially those pertaining to environmental taxes and regulation. The model allows examining the short-term (annual) and medium-term economic effects, as well as long-term effects of E3 policies for a period of 20 years. Hence, E3ME combines the features of short-term and medium-term sector models estimated using econometric methods with the features of computational general equilibrium models. The E3ME model includes 42 product/industry sectors (OECD classification), with energy sector further disaggregated to include energy-environment interaction and 16 service sectors. It is intended for analysis of macroeconomic effects (with emphasis on environmental components) of environmental economic policies, especially from the aspect of environmental taxation and regulation, for 33 European countries (EU27, Norway, Switzerland, Iceland, Croatia, Turkey, and Macedonia) as a whole. It also allows analysis of environmental effects in each country8. The structure of E3ME is based on the System of National Accounts (ESA 95), with additional links to demand for energy and environmental emissions. The model includes a total of 33 sets of econometrically estimated equations which also include components of the GDP (consumption, investment, international trade), prices, demand for energy, and demand for raw materials. Each set of equations is broken down by countries and by sectors. E3ME also allows analyzing the effects of particular scenarios as measured by numerous economic, energy, and environmental indicators. The model is based on the data for the period from 1970 to 2010 and annual projections until the year 2050. The main sources of data include Eurostat, AMECO DC ECFIN database, and IEA; this data set is further complemented by OECD STAN and other databases. Any gaps in the data are estimated using adjusted software algorithms. For a detailed description of the E3ME model, see E3ME Manual (2012). 6 For a detailed description of methodological approaches in modelling the relations between the environment and the economy, see Scasny et al. (2009). 7 The model was developed and is maintained by the company Cambridge Econometrics. 8 See E3ME Manual (2012) for more detailed description. 3.1. EFFECTS OF ECOLOGICAL TAXATION (GREEN TAX) IN THE E3ME MODEL One of the purposes of the E3ME model is to provide consistent and coherent analysis of fiscal policy and its relation to greenhouse gas emissions. The E3ME model allows examining how carbon and energy taxes affect the reduction of environmental emissions, as well as how other taxation and economic policies affect reduction of emissions. The effect of a taxing carbon dioxide emissions (and energy consumption) in the E3ME model on prices and wages is based on two key assumptions. The first assumption is that the effect of tax is transmitted through the price of fuel and any use of subsequent tax revenue to reduce other taxes. Other effects are not modelled. The second assumption is that import of fuels and domestic production are taxed in proportion to the CO2 emission rate and energy value of the fuel, while fuel exports are not taxed. It is assumed that this tax is paid by the fuel producers and importers. This tax is then levied on the final users through higher fuel prices. Another assumption is that the industry will transmit these additional fuel costs on its buyers in the form of higher prices of commodities (goods and services). An increase in the final price is therefore a result of direct and indirect effect of tax on a particular good or service. If tax revenue is used to reduce the rates of taxes levied on the employers, this will result in a decrease of labour costs and, in turn, a drop in production costs. These changes, too, will then be transmitted forward within the E3ME model (E3ME Manual, 2012). Net effect of tax on prices of products and imports will be transmitted to consumer prices, resulting in a change in the consumption of goods and services. Such change will depend on individual ecotax and the price elasticity of the affected commodities. Higher prices of goods and services will lead to demands for higher wages. Econometric studies have confirmed that in the long run, entire tax is levied on the consumers. This fact is integrated into the E3ME model as a part of its long-term solution. In the E3ME model, ecotaxes indirectly influence (through direct effect on prices and wages) the macroeconomic parameters such as fuel consumption, production, employment in particular sectors etc.). Namely, a change in the price of fuels resulting from ecotax will, depending on the elasticity of substitution, lead to a change in fuel consumption. Increase of fuel prices due to higher taxes will cause changes in consumer prices, which will be reflected in substitution in consumer expenditure, change of export activity, and change in the relation between domestic production and imports. These changes will in turn affect, via feedback loop, the use of various types of fuel. A reduction in labour costs resulting from "recycling" of tax revenue will initially have a direct positive effect on employment, followed by an indirect effect through relative price competitiveness thereon as more commodities (goods and services) are produced in labour intensive industries. 4. RESULTS OF THE MODEL Below we present the results of the introduction of the additional carbon tax. We firstly assume that all revenue generated from ecotax is allocated for reduction of the budget deficit or increase of the budget surplus. In subsequent analyses, ecotaxes will be recycled in various ways, e.g. they will be used to reduce the taxes levied on labour costs. The analysis will be based in section 4.2. on a comparison to a base projection (baseline scenario), and in section 4.3. on a comparison to a budget recycling projection. Results will be presented in the form of a deviation from the base projection and the budget recycling projection. Therefore, we continue by presenting the assumption underlying the base projection, and the way in which this projection was generated. 4.1. DESCRIPTION OF THE BASE PROJECTION (BASELINE SCENARIO) AND UNDERLYING ASSUMPTIONS AND THE ESTIMATION METODOLOGY TOGETHER WITH PARAMETER RESULTS It is important that the baseline projection (baseline scenario) in the framework of the E3ME model is consistent with the forecasts used in other analyses. The underlying assumption of the baseline projection was that the E3ME projection was consistent with the slightly modified projection of the European commission (modified projection PRIMES BASELINE 2009). PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are also presented in Table A1 in the Appendix. Following is a description of the key stages in modelling of the base projection. Inputs for the base projection include historical data (data on economic indicators, energy, and the environment, obtained from different sources (Eurostat, IEA etc.), estimates of parameters for endogenous variables, and fundamental assumptions. Historical data on economic indicators for Slovenia (employment, output, consumption, exports etc.) is used up to and including 2010. The indicators were calculated from the data published by Eurostat in February 2012. Historical data on energy components (energy consumption by types of fuel etc.) and environmental components is derived from the World Energy Outlook for the period up to 2009. Endogenous variables are determined using the functions estimated based on historical data. There are around 33 variables for which stochastic functions are estimated. However these variables may well be disaggregated in two dimensions (e.g. there are 19 fuel users and 33 countries) so we will not provide the specification of each variable. Below we first describe the general procedure how these stochastic functions are estimated and then show one example of such function and its parameters for Slovenia. The functional form of the equations and the parameters are based on the cointegration and error-correction methodology (Engle and Granger, 1987, and Hendry et al., 1984). The process involves two stages. The first-stage is a levels relationship, where an attempt is made to identify the existence of a cointegrating relationship between the chosen variables, selected on the basis of economic theory and a priori reasoning. For example the aggregate energy demand (FRO) is specified as follows: FR0.. = a.n + a.,FRY.+a ,PREN..f + a.,FRTD..+ a.. .ZRDM + a.„nm,f i,j,t i,j,0 i,j,1 i,j,t i,j,2 i,j,t i,j,3 i,j,t i,j,4 t i,j,5ZRDTt + + a. ,FRK.. f u..f i,j,6 i.j.t + i.j.t where FRY is economic output of energy users i in region j, PREN is average fuel price (across all fuels) deflated by unit cost in region j, FRTD is R&D expenditure by energy user i in region j, ZRDM is EU investment of R&D in machinery, ZRDT is EU investment of R&D in transport, and FRK is investment by energy user i in region j If a cointegrating relationship exists, then the second stage regression, known as the error-correction representation, is implemented. It involves a dynamic, first-difference, regression of all the variables from the first stage, along with lags of the dependent variable, lagged differences of the exogenous variables, and the error-correction term (the lagged residual from the first stage regression). Due to limitations of data size, however, only one lag of each variable is included in the second-stage. For example in case of aggregate energy demand the error correction equation is specified as: AFR0. = b.. „ + b..,.FRY + b....PREN + b..,DFRTD..f + b.. .AZRDM + b..,AZRDTf i,j,t i,j,0 i,j,1A i,j,t i,j,2A j,t i,j,3 i,j,t i,j,4 t i,j,5 t + b.. ,AFRK. + b.. 7AFR0..,, + g.ECM. ,f, i,j,6 i,j,t Ц,7 i,j,t-l Ощ, i,j,t-l , where A is difference and ECM is error correction. Stationarity tests on the residual from the levels equation are performed to check whether a cointegrating set is obtained. Due to the size of the model, the equations are estimated individually rather than through a cointegrating VAR. For both regressions, the estimation technique used is instrumental variables, principally because of the simultaneous nature of many of the relationships (for example wage, employment and price determination). E3ME's parameter estimate is carried out using a customised set of software routines based in the Ox programming language (Doornik, 2007). The main advantage of using this approach is that parameters for all sectors and countries may be estimated using an automated approach. The estimation produces a full set of standard econometric diagnostics, including standard errors and tests for endogeneity. However all the estimation procedures and test are carried out by Cambridge Econometrics, the developer of the software9. In Table A2 in appendix we provide a summary of the model equations, giving an overview of which variables are used, units of measurement and functional form. A full list of the variables included in E3ME model is available on request. In Appendix 1 we also present in more detail the agregate demand for energy function and the estimated parameters for Slovenia. The other functions and parameters for Slovenia are available upon request. 9 A list of equation results can be made available on request. For each equation, the following information will be given: summary of results, full list of parameter results, full list of standard deviations. The gaps in any of the E3ME time series was filled by software that was developed by the Cambridge Econometrics. This software uses growth rates and shares between sectors and variables to estimate missing data points, both in cases of interpolation and extrapolation. More precisely, " The most straightforward case is when the growth rates of a variable are known and so the level can be estimated from these growth rates, as long as the initial level is known. Sharing is used when the time-series data of an aggregation of sectors are available but the individual time series is not. In this case, the sectoral time series can be calculated by sharing the total, using either actual or estimated shares. In the case of extrapolation, it is often the case that aggregate data for a number of sectors are available, although the sectoral disaggregation at the E3ME level is not; for example, government expenditure is a good proxy for the total growth in education, health and defence. A special procedure has been put in place to estimate the growth in more disaggregated sectors so that the sum of these matches the known total, while the individual sectoral growth follows the characteristics of each sector. Interpolation is used when no external source is available, to estimate the path interval, at the beginning and end of which data are available". (E3ME, 2014, page 34) Basic assumptions are derived from various sources. The sources are presented in Table A3 in the Appendix. For Slovenia, the values of these assumptions for the period 20102013 are presented in Table A4 in the Appendix. In the same table values of assumptions for particular commodities (e.g. energy prices, fuel prices etc.) are also presented. The baseline scenario is therefore based on all government measures implemented until mid 2010. For example, the CO2 price is determined on the measures introduced by the Slovenian government by mid 2010. The process of ensuring compliance of the base projection in the E3ME model involves three stages. This is in fact a calibration process. The first stage in reconciling the E3ME projections with the published and slightly modified forecast PRIMES BASELINE 2009 (EU Energy trends to 2030, Baseline scenario 2009, European Commission, 2010). It includes ensuring consistency and transformation of the data into a suitable form. This means that different model dimensions have to be brought into line (geographic coverage, temporal aspect, sector coverage etc.). Transformed data are then saved in a separate file. In the next stage, the model is resolved in such way that model results match the slightly modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts saved in a separate file. This is the calibrated forecasting process. In this forecast, the model solves its equations and compares the differences in results with the data saved in the database. Model results are substituted with values from the forecast database. Differences between results and forecasts are saved in a separate database called the "residual" database. In the last stage, the model is solved again using the "residual" database as well. This is the so-called endogenous baseline projection. According the theory, the final result should be the same as in the case of calibrated forecast. In practice, the match is not 100-percent (see, E3ME manual, pages 40-41). In the E3ME model framework, the calibration process with modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts is carried out based on the trends (growth rates) rather than based on levels. This is because historical data in the E3ME model are newer that the data from the modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009. Calibrations for PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are made for the key economic variables and demand for energy (variables FRO, FRO1, FRO2 ... FRO12) and data on emissions (variables GHG, FCO2 etc.). However, since PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts are based on the year 2010 and they do not include the most recent changes in the economic environment (the economic crisis), short-term calibration for macroeco-nomic variables is conducted based on AMECO short-term forecasts. Therefore, the baseline scenario is made based on the modified PRIMES BASELINE 2009 forecasts. The key advantage of the endogenous baseline projection is that it allows us to analyse different scenarios in order to find out how the results change relative to the baseline scenario. There are two baseline endogenous projections: SI endogenous baseline projection and EU endogenous baseline projection. For the SI endogenous baseline projection, calibration is only carried out for Slovenia while other European regions are treated as exogenous. This projection is used in analysis of scenarios that only affect Slovenia (e.g. a change in domestic tax rate). EU endogenous baseline projection involves simultaneously solving the E3ME model for the entire Europe. This projection is used for scenarios that will affect the entire Europe (e.g. a change in oil prices). If this solution is used, results for Slovenia will also include secondary effects from other European regions, brought about through international trade. Since the introduction of the additional carbon tax in Slovenia is only affecting the Slovenian economy, SI endogenous projection will be used. The remaining part of Europe is treated as exogenous10. It is important to stress, that all scenarios that will be presented11 are based on (1) historical data up to and including the year 2009 (energy and environmental components) or the year 2010 (economic components); (2) on government measures implemented by mid 2010; (3) and on long-term and short-term trends energy and environmental components, that are based on the European Commission projections from 2009 (PRIMES BASELINE 2009). Long-term trends for macroeconomic components are also based on European Commission projections from 2009 (PRIMES BASELINE 2009) while short-term macroeconomic components are based on the AMECO projections. This means that the effects of the economic crisis are only partially included and, as a result, the below results should be used with caution. 4.2. ANALYSIS OF INTRODUCTION OF AN ADDITIONAL CARBON TAX ON THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY It is assumed within the E3ME model that payment of carbon tax (tax on carbon dioxide) is levied on the users of fuels based on their emissions; however, only sectors outside ETS are taxed in order to avoid double taxation. The cost, or burden, of the tax is then shifted to the consumers through higher fuel prices. 10 We have also introduced the additional carbon tax in Slovenia by using EU endogenous baseline projection. The results were very similar. 11 Values of particular variables for all scenarios to be used herein are presented in Table A5 in the appendix. In consequence, this means that we can expect the prices to rise while demand for fuel drops. It is assumed that higher prices will lead to a drop in real income. We can expect household consumption expenditure to decrease, which will in turn decrease demand and cause a drop in gross domestic product. As we assumed this change would not affect the European economy, we expect this will result in a drop of export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy due to higher prices, which will lead to a further decrease in GDP. According to economic theory, the amount of carbon tax should be equal to the social cost incurred as a result of carbon pollution. Yohe et al. (2007) reviewed the estimates and found that costs estimates are highly unpredictable as they range from USD 1 per ton of carbon (tC) up to USD 1,500 per ton of carbon (tC). Average estimate of social cost of pollution with carbon dioxide for 2005 was USD 43/tC, with a standard deviation of USD 83/tC. The authors found that these costs rise at a rate of 2 to 4 percent per year. Assuming 4-percent annual growth since 2005, carbon pollution cost in 2012 would amount to an average of USD 55/tC or EUR 42/tC (i.e. EUR 11.5/tCO2. We set the amount of extra carbon tax to EUR 15/tCO2 (i.e. EUR 55/tC)12. In the article we compare two scenarios: baseline scenario in which no extra carbon tax is introduced and the projection of an introduction of an additional annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15 per ton of CO2 (EUR 15 per ton of carbon) for sectors beyond ETS, where all ecotax is recycled into the government budget. Comparison between the two projections is made for some key economic (household consumption expenditure, exports, gross domestic product, total manufacturing output, employment), energy (average fuel prices, demand for energy), and environmental variables (greenhouse emissions) which are presented in detail below. Average fuel prices including tax (PJRT13) change the most in the first year following the introduction of the carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) (2012) when they rise by 3.67% relative to the baseline scenario in which no extra carbon tax is introduced. After the initial price hike, the price reaches a steady state at a higher figure which is maintained throughout the examined period. The difference in the average fuel price between the baseline scenario and projection that assumes an additional carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/tC) is approximately 3.5% throughout the period at hand (until 2030). As expected, the introduction of an extra carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) drives up the average prices of fuel, which in turn causes a decrease in demand for fuels for energy production (FRO14). This drop relative to the baseline scenario is relatively the largest in the initial period, after which the decrease in demand for energy is steadied or slowed down. In 2013, for example, demand for energy resulting from the intro duction of the carbon tax was projected to be lower by 0.83% compared to the baseline scenario; in 2020 by 12 Determination of the size of the ecotax has been aligned with the Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development (UMAR). We have also used other numbers for ecotax, but we do not report them in the article. 13 PJRT = Average fuel price including tax (in EUR/toe). The model assumes 12 different fuel consumers. 14 FRO = Total demand for energy is in E3ME model measured in thousand tons toe. Model assumes 12 different fuel consumers. 1.64%; and in 2025 by 1.9%. Initial increase in prices and a considerable drop in demand relative to the baseline scenario are followed by a higher and steady level of fuel prices and accordingly lower demand for energy throughout the period of examination. Household consumption expenditure (RSC15) is one of the most important macroeco-nomic aggregates, since it takes the largest share of GDP structure. Introduction of extra annual carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) would lead to the highest relative drop of household consumption expenditure in 2013 when the decrease amounts to 0.45% relative to the baseline scenario with no introduction of carbon tax. In principle, higher average prices of fuel lead to a decrease in real income which in turn decreases household consumption expenditure. This would result in a drop in aggregate demand and cause a decrease in gross domestic product. After 2013, the difference relative to the baseline scenario gradually decreases and by 2020, for example, consumption is only 0.27% lower compared to the baseline scenario. As expected, the difference between the two scenarios is the largest at the beginning of the period; after 2013, it is gradually decreasing. Moreover, the data shows a relatively low effect of the introduction of the carbon tax on the change in consumption. The reasons can be found in the time lag as the consumers require some time to adjust their behaviour and consumption pattern. If the extra annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) is introduced, exports (RSX16) will decrease relative to the baseline scenario in which no carbon tax is introduced in the short run (until 2017), and increase after 2018. Such development is expected as we assumed the change would not affect the European economy. Higher prices expectedly hinder the export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy; however, the export sector's agility and dynamic character in terms of development of new technological solutions and updates will allow it to neutralize relatively quickly such loss of competitiveness. It should also be noted that changes in exports relative to the baseline scenario are very small (up to a maximum of 0.009%), which points to a relatively low impact of the carbon tax on Slovenian exports. Introduction of extra annual carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) would lead to the highest drop of Slovenia's GDP (RGDP17) in 2013 when the decrease would amount to 0.3% relative to the baseline scenario with no introduction of carbon tax. This is consistent with our expectations. It has been shown in our previous analysis that higher fuel prices lead to a decrease of real income. As a result, household consumption expenditure will decrease, which will in turn decrease demand and cause a drop in gross domestic product. As we assumed this change would not affect the European economy, higher prices would also result in a drop of export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy, which would lead to a further decrease in GDP. Moreover, the data shows a relatively low effect of the introduction of the said tax on the change in GDP. After 2013, the difference between the two scenarios gradually decreases and by 2020, for example, GDP is only 15 RSC = Household consumption expenditure is in E3ME model measured in EUR million. The model assumes 43 different types of expenditure. 16 RSX = Exports are measured in E3ME model in million euro. 17 RGDP = Gross domestic product is in E3ME model measured by the expenditure method in current market prices in millions of euro. 0.12% lower in case of introduction of the carbon tax compared to the baseline scenario. This conforms to our expectations and the theoretical findings as economic agents require some time to adjust to the new circumstances. Businesses need time to implement technological improvements and updates, and consumers need time to adjust their consumption behaviour and patterns. We are also interested in the effect of an extra yearly carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) on manufacturing output (QR18). The highest drop relative to the baseline scenario would be in 2015. In that year, the difference would amount to 0.32%. Here too, it is evident that introduction of carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/ tC) has a relatively small effect on production. The difference between the two scenarios is, expectedly, the highest at the start of the period. After 2013, this difference is gradually decreasing so that the deviation from the baseline scenario in 2015 is no more than 0.01%. Technological and organizational updates allowed the enterprises to adapt to the new conditions after a certain period of time. According to the projection, the latter effect prevails in the long run, after 2027. Employment (YRE19) shows a similar dynamics as manufacturing output. Employment is gradually decreasing relative to the baseline scenario. The highest drop in comparison to the baseline scenario can be seen in 2016 when it amounts to 0.36%. There are hardly any differences between the two scenarios at the end of the period. The effect of an additional carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (or EUR 55/tC) on employment appears to be relatively low, similarly to the effect on GDP and manufacturing output. As expected, the introduction of an extra carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) gradually decreases greenhouse gas emissions (RGHG20) in CO2 equivalents. This includes emissions of CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs and SF6. For example, the highest drop in emissions relative to the baseline scenario is seen in 2012 (by 0.6%) and 2013 (by an extra 0.5%) to -1.2%. The decrease in emissions in comparison to the baseline scenario is steadied at approximately 2% after 2020. 4.3. ANALYSIS OF DIFFERENT FORMS OF REVENUE RECYCLING IN CASE OF EXTRA CARBON TAX IN THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY Introduction of an extra annual carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC) on an annual basis for the period 2012-2030 would result in additional annual tax revenue ranging from a minimum amount of EUR 144.6 million in year 2012 to a maximum amount of EUR 160.1 million in year 2020. The additional tax revenue can be allocated to the economy through different revenue recycling options. We compare the following five revenue recycling options (in each option we have introduced a yearly carbon tax of EUR 15/tCO2 (EUR 55/tC), while other assumptions remain the same as in the baseline scenario): 18 QR = total manufacturing output (EUR million). The model is based on an analysis of 42 different sectors. 19 YRE = Employment (thousands). The model is based on an analysis of 42 different industries. 20 RGHG = Greenhouse gas emissions (in CO2 equivalent thousands of tons) a) The first scenario analyses the effects of introduction of the extra carbon tax and revenue recycling through a decrease in the budget deficit and tax revenue. b) In the second scenario, we study the effects of revenue recycling through a decrease in social security contributions for the workers/employees, equivalent to the amount of green tax revenue (fiscal neutrality). Although the yearly decrease of workers' social contributions varies by year, depending on the green tax collected, the average decrease in the period 2012-2030 was 0.6 percentage points i.e. the worker social contributions were on average equal to 18.0% in the observed period (2012-2030). c) In the third scenario we analyse the effects of revenue recycling through a corresponding decrease in social security contributions payable by the employers subject to the principle of fiscal neutrality. Although the yearly decrease of employers' social contributions varies by year, depending on the green tax collected, the average decrease in the period 2012-2030 was 0.6 percentage points i.e. the employers' social contributions were on average equal to 13.0% in the observed period. d) In the fourth scenario we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers' social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. Assuming fiscal neutrality, green tax revenue were first allocated to the budget (period 2012-2016) and for the period 2017-2030 we decreased the workers' social security contributions on average to 18.1%. e) In the fifth scenario, revenue is recycled through a decrease in budget deficit in the first five years (2012-2016); then, social security contributions payable by the employers are decreased by the relevant amount. Applying the principle of fiscal neutrality, the latter were decreased on average to 13.1% (0.5 percentage points) in the period 2017-2030. A comparison between different types of recycling will be made especially for some key economic variables (household consumption expenditure, gross domestic product, manufacturing output, employment). Analysis of revenue recycling will be based on a comparison of the second, third, fourth, and fifth scenario, respectively, to the first one. We wish to determine the existence of the double dividend based on a decrease of some social security contributions, improvement in cost competitiveness and the resulting rise in GDP and employment. Effect on household consumption expenditure Figure 1 presents the effect on household consumption expenditure (RSC) in case of different options of recycling of the revenue generated by the extra yearly carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15/tCO2. In our analysis, four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th scenario) are compared to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Figure 1 shows that the positive effect on household consumption expenditure in all four scenarios is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). This is expected as additional relief through lower social contributions may increase the general population's purchasing power as net wages rise. Furthermore, it can be observed that revenue recycling through workers' social contributions has a higher effect on household consumption expenditure than recycling through social security contributions payable by the employers in the entire period at hand (both relative to the first scenario). The difference in household consumption expenditure between the two revenue recycling options is decreasing through the years. The reasons can be found in the fact that a decrease in employers' social security contributions would translate to a lower extent into an increase in net wages and the resulting increase in consumption than it would be the case if social security contributions were decreased for the workers. The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers' social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. In this case, too, decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on household consumption expenditure than a decrease of social security contributions for the employers (both in comparison to the first scenario). Similar as before, the differences between the two scenarios through the years are gradually decreasing. Figure 1 also shows that the best scenarios from the aspect of revenue recycling are the ones that decrease social security contributions for the workers (scenarios 2 and 4). These two scenarios are only different in the first five years; after that, their results tend to match. Similar match can be seen between the two scenarios in which the employer's social security contributions are reduced. It should also be noted that the differences between all scenarios referred to are relatively small. Figure 1: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of effect on household consumption expenditure, RSC. 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 2027 2029 year ■ % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions ■ % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions ■% change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions 0 Source: E3ME program and own calculations. Effect on gross domestic product Figure 2 shows the effect of introduction of a yearly carbon tax in the amount wf EUR 15/ tCO2 on GDP (RGDP) in different cases of tax revenue recycling. In oun analysis, four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th scenario) are compared to the first scenario en which all carbon tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. It is evident from Figure 2 that the positive effect on GDP in all four scenarios is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. This matches our expectations as additional relief of labour costs through a decrease in social security contributions payable by the employers or the workers translates into an increase in household purchasing power and in turn an increase in GDP. The positive effect is stronger in case of revenue recycling through a decrease in worker's social security contributions in the entire period at hand (both relative to the first scenario). The difference between the two revenue recycling options is decreasing through the examined period. The reasons for this can be found in higher household consumption expenditure (see previous section) which is the largest component of GDP. The result is similar in the case where green tax revenue is allocated for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in social security contributions in 2017 and beyond. Decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on household consumption expenditure than a decrease of social security contributions for the employers (both in comparison to the first scenario). In this case, too, the differences between the two scenarios are gradually decreasing through the years. Figure 2 also shows that the best scenarios from the aspect of revenue recycling are the ones that decrease social security contributions for the workers (scenarios 2 and 4). These two scenarios are only different in the first five years; after that, their results tend to match. Similar match can be seen between the two scenarios in which the employer's social security contributions are reduced. It should again be noted that the differences between all scenarios in terms of discrepancy relative to the first scenario are relatively small. Figure 2: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of effect on gross domestic product, RGDP. % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions Effect on total manufacturing output Following is a presentation of the effect of carbon tax introduction on manufacturing output (QR) in case of different forms of recycling. Figure 3 compares four scenarios to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue, is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). It is evident from Figure 3 that the positive effect on manufacturing output in all four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th) is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Higher cost relief through a decrease in social security contributions of the employer or the worker and the resulting improvement in cost efficiency appears to motivate total manufacturing output as well. Recycling through a reduction in social security contributions of the workers has a more positive effect on production than recycling through decrease in social security contributions for the employers in the period 2012-2030 (both relative to the first scenario). The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. In both cases, decrease of social security contributions for the workers has a stronger positive effect on manufacturing output than a decrease in the employer's social security contributions. Again, the differences between all scenarios in terms of discrepancy relative to the first scenario are relatively small. Figure 3: Comparison between different forms of carbon tax revenue recycling from the aspect of total manufacturing output, QR. % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into a decrease of employers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of workers' social security contributions % change between revenue recycling into budget and recycling into budget in the first 5 years, followed by a decrease of employers' social security contributions Effect on employment Following is a presentation of the effect of carbon tax introduction on employment (YRE) in case of different forms of recycling. Four scenarios are compared to the projection in which all carbon tax revenue, is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Figure 4 shows that the positive effect on employment in all four scenarios (2nd, 3rd, 4th, and 5th) is stronger than in case of the projection in which all generated tax reve nue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Higher erosi: ne lief through a decrease in social security contributions (of the employer or the worker) evidently has a positive effect on employment, which is also consistent with the previous lwo figures. Revenue recycling through a decrease of the employer's social security contoibutions has a stronger effect on employment than revenue recycling through workers social security contributions, but only in the short run until the year 2014. In the long run, thr opp>osite is true; after 2015, the difference between the second and the third scenaeio isconstant. If carbon tax revenue is allocated for covering the budget deficit in the period 2012-2016 and for a decrease in social security contributions in 2017 and beyrnd, the conclusion is similar. In this case, too, revenue recycling has a stronger effect in the short ruin (until 2018) if the employer's social security contributions are decreased. Differenced between all analyzed scenarios are relatively s mah in terms of discrepancy relative to the first sc enario. Figure 4: Comparison between different forms of recycling in case of carbon tax introduction from the aspect of employment, YRE 0,7 •Г change btecttn rivinsi recycling into bsOgit and recycling into a (icriati if cirkirt' social ticuriiy cineribseiinc •Г changi bitciin rivinsi recycling into bsOgit and recycling into a (icriati if impliyirt' social ticsriiy cineribseiinc Г changi bitciin rivinsi recycling into bsOgit and recycling into bsOgit in thi first 5 ytart, filliciO by a (icriati if cirkirt' social ticurity cintribstiint 'Го changi bitciin rivinsi recycling into bsOgit and recycling into bs^t in thi firtt 5 ytart, fil^ctd by a rtcrtact if tmpliytrt' ticial ttcsrity cintribstiint 5. CONCLUSION The main goal of the environmental tax reform is economic and environmental improvement. Environmental dividend involves reduction in emissions, while economic dividend has to do with improved cost competitiveness, higher growth, and higher employment. Our primary goal was to determine the effect of an extra carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2 i.e. EUR 55 per ton of carbon) in the period 2012-2030 on Slovenian economy, in order to determine whether a carbon tax would indeed yield a double dividend. In the first section, we analysed the effects of the introduction of a yearly carbon tax (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) relative to the baseline projection (in which no tax is introduced) in the period 2012-2030, using the E3ME model. Our analysis has shown that average prices of fuels will increase which will reduce demand for fuels. Higher prices will also lead to lower household consumption expenditure, which would decrease aggregate demand and result in a drop of GDP. GDP would be additionally decreased in the short run by lower export competitiveness of the Slovenian economy, resulting from higher prices, as we assumed that the change in prices would not affect the European economy. In the medium and long run, the effect of carbon tax on the change in GDP, relative to the baseline scenario (i.e. no carbon tax), is always lower. This conforms to our expectations and the theoretical findings as economic agents require some time to adjust to the new circumstances. The E3ME model has shown that Slovenian export sector would look to introduce new technological solutions and updates, thereby neutralizing relatively quickly the negative effects of the introduction of the carbon tax on the competitiveness of the Slovenian economy. Similar dynamics and oscillation as in GDP can be observed in manufacturing output and employment. Greenhouse emissions, too, are reduced in the model, at approximately the same rate. Economic policy developers in Slovenia, as in many other European countries with implemented environmental tax reform, should be aware that introduction of a carbon tax in Slovenia would have more negative effects in the short run than in the medium and long run. It is therefore of key importance for the success of the green tax reform to introduce the extra carbon tax gradually, transparently, and predictably. This would allow enough time for economic agents to adapt, and for economic policy developers to evaluate the first effects of the green tax reform and to make any adjustments if discrepancies from the planned goals are identified in the course of the reform. This would also prevent recurring discussions as to the urgency of increase of some tax rates and political pressure to decrease such rates as a result of higher prices of oil and petrochemicals in the global market. In the second section, we used the E3ME model to analyze the effects of different forms of tax revenue recycling, either through a decrease in the budget deficit or through a decrease of social security contributions payable by either the employers or the workers, in case of a yearly carbon tax in the amount of EUR 15 per ton of CO2 in the period 2012-2030. Our analysis has shown that recycling through lowering the social security contributions for workers (2nd and 4th scenario) and employers (3rd and 5th scenario) have a stronger positive effect on household consumption expenditure than the scenario in which all revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit (first scenario). Differences between the recycling scenarios are relatively small. Additional relief through a decrease in social security contributions in case of an extra carbon tax would increase the purchasing power of the general population (household consumption expenditure), which would in turn increase the GDP. Higher cost relief through a decrease in social security contributions also has a positive effect on total manufacturing output and employment. We have also shown that recycling through a decrease in social security contributions of workers has a stronger positive economic effect than recycling through a decrease in employers' social security contributions in the entire period at hand. The result is similar in the case where we allocate the green tax revenue for covering the budget deficit in the period from 2012 to 2016, and for a decrease in workers' or employers' social security contributions in 2017 and thereafter. Policy implications for the Slovenian government are twofold. Firstly, scenarios in which all revenue is allocated exclusively for lowering the social security contributions for workers/employers have a stronger positive economic effect than the scenario in which all revenue is allocated exclusively for covering the budget deficit. Secondly, the optimal fiscal instrument for improving the environmental (first dividend) and economic welfare (second dividend) seems to be recycling through a decrease in social security contributions of workers. The reasons can be found in the fact that a decrease in employers' social security contributions would translate to a lower extent into an increase in net wages and the resulting increase in consumption than it would be the case if social security contributions were decreased for the workers. However, an environmental tax reform cannot be successful if the political reality in Slovenia is disregarded. As a rule, economists design optimum policy mixes for the attainment of certain goals; however, politics often requires compromises. Experience from other countries has shown that the key to their success was the high rate of consent of all political parties and civil society regarding the urgency of an environmental tax reform. Therefore, the Slovenian government should inform the public about the negative effects of an extra carbon tax. Public support will be higher, if an effective system of measures is put into place to neutralize the harmful effects of the additional carbon tax. REFERENCES Albrecht, J. (2006). The use of consumption taxes to re-launch green tax reforms. International Review of Law and Economics, 26(1), 88-103. Barker, T.S. & Ekins, P. & Johnstone, N. (1995). Global Warming and Energy Demand. London: Routledge. Baron, R. (1997). Economic/Fiscal Instruments: Competitiveness Issues Related to Carbon/Energy Taxation Policies and Measures for Common Action. Working Paper No. 14. Paris: OECD. Benoit, B. (2000). Environmental tax reform: does it work? A survey of the empirical evidence. Ecological Economics, 34(1), 19-32. Berkhout, G., Ferrer-i-Carbonell A. & Muskens, A.C. (2001). Het effect van de REB op huishoudelijk energie-gevruik. EEN econometrische analyse. Amsterdam. Bentzen, J. & Engsted, T. (1993). Short- and long-run elasticities in energy demand: a cointegration approach. Energy Economics, 15(1) 9-16. Bovenberg, L. & Goulder, L.H. (1997). Cost of environmentally motivated taxes in the presence of other taxes: general equilibrium analyses. National Tax Journal, 50(1), 59-87. Camecon (2012). Teaching course. 15th-16th March, 2012. Carraro, C., Galeotti, M. & Gallo, M. (1996). Environmental taxation and unemployment: Some evidence on the 'double dividend hypothesis' in Europe. Journal of Public Economics, 62(1/2), 141-181. Ciaschini, M., Pretalori, R., Severini, F., Socci, C. (2012): Regional Double Dividend from Environmental Tax Reform: An Application from the Italian Economy. Research in Economics, 66(3): 273-283. Clinch, P., Dunne, L. & Dresner, S. (2006). Environmental and wider implications of political impediments to environmental tax reform. Energy Policy, 34(8), 960-970. Coxhead, I. (2000). Tax Reform and the Environment in Developing Economies: Is a Double Dividend Possible? Wisconsin-Madison Agricultural and Applied Economics Staff Paper No. 431. Madison: University of Wisconsin-Madison. Doornik, J. (2007). Ox: An Object-Oriented Matrix Language. London: Timberlake Consultants Press. De Mooij, R.A. (1999). The double dividend of an environmental tax reform. In Bergh, V. (Ed.), Handbook of Environmental and Resource Economics (pp. 600-613). London: Edward Elgar. E3ME Manual (2012). http://www.camecon.com/Libraries/Downloadable_Files/E3ME_Manual.sflb.ashx (Accessed on 20.12.2012) E3ME (2014). Technical Manual, Version 6.0. Cambridge: Cambridge Econometrics. Ekins, P. (2009). Resource Productivity, Environmental Tax Reform and Sustainable Growth in Europe. Berlin: Anglo-German Foundation. Engle, R.F. & C.W.J. Granger, C.W.J. (1987). Cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55, 251-76. European Commission (2010). EU energy trends to 2030 - update 2009. Brussels: European Commission. European Commission (2012). Taxation trend in the EU. Brussels: European Commission. Franzén, M. & Sterner, T (1995). Long-run Demand Elasticities for Gasoline. In Barker, T. & Johnstone, N. & Ekins, P. (eds.), Global Warming and Energy Elasticities. London: Routledge. Fraser, I. & Waschik, R. (2013): The Double Dividend Hypothesis in CGE Model: Specific factors and the Carbon Case. Energy Economics, 39, 283-295. Gimenez, E. & Rodriguez, M. (2010). Reevaluating the first and the second dividends of environmental tax reforms. Energy Policy, 38(11), 6654-6661. Glomm, G., Kawaguchi, D. & Sepulveda, F. (2008). Green taxes and double dividends in a dynamic economy. Journal of policy modeling, 30(1), 19-32. Goulder, L.H. (1995). Environmental taxation and the ''double dividend'': a reader's guide. International Tax and Public Finance, 2(2), 155-182. Hansen, M. & Holger, H. (2000). Green tax reform in Denmark. In Schlegelmilch, Kai (Ed.), Green Budget reform in Europe: Countries at the forefront (pp. 139-145). Berlin: Springer. Hendry, D. F. & Pagan, A. & Sargan, J.D. (1984). Dynamic specification. In Griliches, Z. & Intriligator, M.D. (eds), Handbook of Econometrics, Vol II (pp. 1023-1100). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Hoerner, B. (2001). Environmental tax reform: The European Experience. Washingtom DC: Center for Sustainable Economy. Holmlund, B. & Kolm, A.S. (2000). Environmental tax reform in a small open economy with structural unemployment. International Tax and Public Finance, 7(3), 315-333. Hunt, L. & Manning, N. (1989). Energy price- and income-elasticities of demand: some estimates for the UK using the cointegration procedure. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 36(2), 183-193. Johansson, O. & Schipper, L. (1997). Measuring the long-run fuel demand of cars. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 31(3), 277-292. Johansson, B. (2000). The carbon tax in Sweden. In: OECD, Innovation and the Environment (pp. 85-94). Paris: OECD. Koskela, E. & Schob, R. (1999). Alleviating unemployment: the case for green tax reform. European Economic Review, 43(9), 1723-1746. Kosonen, K. & Nicodème, G. (2009). The role of fiscal instruments in environmental policy. Working paper No. 2719, Munchen: CESifo. Labandeira, X. & Labeaga, J. (1999). Combining inpt-ouput analysis and microsimulations to acces the effects of carbon taxation on spanish households. Fiscal studies, 20(3), 305-320. Labandeira, X., Labeaga, J.M. & Rodriguez, M. (2004). Green tax reforms in Spain. European Environment, 14(5), 290-299. Hua Li, Longyang Ren (2012). China's Provincial Tax Structure Optimization: Double Dividend of Energy and Efficiency. Finance & Trade Economics, 10(3). Ludewig, D., Meyer, B. & Schlegelmilch, K. (2010). Greening the Budget: Pricing Carbon and Cutting Energy Subsidies to reduce the financial deficit in Germany. Washington DC: Heinrich Boll Stiftung. Manresa, A. & Sancho, F. (2005). Implementing a double dividend: recycling ecotaxes towards lower labour taxes. Energy Policy, 33(12), 1577-1585 Morgenstern, R. (1995). Environmental Taxes: Dead or Alive? Discussion Paper 95-03. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. OECD (2007). Employment Outlook. Paris: OECD. Parry, I. & Oates, W. (1998). Policy Analysis in a Second Best World. Discussion paper No. 98-48. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Patuelli, R., Nijkamp, P. & Pels, E. (2005). Environmental tax reform and the double dividend: A meta-analytical performance assessment. Ecological Economics, 55(4), 564-583. Pigou, A.C. (1920). The Economics of Welfare. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson. Roed, L. (2006). Distributional effects of environmental taxes on transportation - evidence from Engel curves in the USA. Journal of Consumer Policy, 29(39), 301-318. Sandmo, A. (1975). Optimal taxation in the presence of externalities. Swedish Journal of Economics, 77(1), 86-98. Schöb, R. (2003). The Double Dividend Hypothesis of Environmental Taxes: A Survey. Working paper No. 946. Munchen: CESifo. Speck, S., Jilkova, J. (2009). Design of environmental tax reforms in Europe. Carbon energy taxation: lessons from Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Scasny, M., Piša, V., Pollitt, H. & Chewpreecha, U. (2009). Analyzing Macroeconomic Effects of Environmental Taxation in the Czech Republic with the Econometric E3ME Model. Journal of Economics and Finance, 59(5), 460-491. Tiezzi, S. (2001). The welfare effects of carbon taxation in Italian households. Working paper No. 337. Siena: Dipartimento di Economica Politica, Universita degli Studi di Siena. Tuladhar, S.D. & Wilcoxen, P.J. (1999). An Econometric Look at the Double Dividend Hypothesis. National Tax Association Proceedings, 57-62. Turner, K., Pearce, D. & Bateman, I. (1994). Environmental economics: An elementary introduction. Prentice Hall: Pearson Education. West, S. & Williams, R. (2004). Estimates from a Consumer demands system: Implication for the incidence of environmental taxes. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47(3), 535-558. Yohe, G.W., Lasco, R.D., Ahmad, Q.K., Arnell, N.W., Cohen, S.J., Hope, C., Janetos, A.C. & Perez, R.T. (2007). Perspectives on climate change and sustainability. In Parry, M.L., Canziani, O.F., Palutikof, J.P., van der Linden, P.J. & Hanson, C.E. (Eds.), Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (pp. 811-841). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. APPENDIX Table nei -.PRIMES (Baseline 2009) for Slovenia. SUMMARY ENERGY BALANCE AND INDICATORS (A) ktoe 1ЭЭ0 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 ■ЭО-'ОО ■00-10 •10--20 '20-30 Annual % Change Production 2902 3020 ЗОЙ 5 3492 3657 4019 4221 4801 4928 0.6 1.7 1.4 1.6 Solids 1432 1210 1082 1104 1252 1505 f573 745 823 -29 1.7 23 -0-3 OH 3 2 1 а 0 0 □ Я 0 -10 4 Natural gas 20 te 6 3 А 0 0 0 0 -11-4 -4.0 Nuclear 1102 1245 ■226 t518 I557 1557 1557 2004 2904 0.3 2,4 D.O 6.4 Renewable energy sources 254 542 788 787 645 057 1091 1152 1201 125 0.7 25 15 Hydro 254 279 330 208 336 353 365 360 363 2.7 02 D5 0.1 Biomass & Waste 0 263 45£ 489 502 56В 053 600 7t5 0.9 27 0.0 Wra D 0 0 0 0 6 14 20 24 52 Solar and öfters 0 □ о 0 6 31 57 74 92 26.2 45 Geothermal fl 0 0 а 0 1 1 1 t 28.1 4.1 Net Imports 2572 3063 3381 3825 4276 4824 5246 4846 4586 2-3 2.4 2.1 -15 Solids 130 186 245 323 260 203 373 233 210 65 0.9 35 -5.3 Oil 1804 2230 2430 2004 Э075 3546 3735 3645 3474 3-0 24 20 -0-7 - Crude al and Feedstocks 59B 589 151 0 1 1 1 1 1 -125 -382 15 -0.4 -Oil produco 1206 1650 2278 2604 3074 3544 3734 3644 3473 05 3.D 2.0 -0.7 Natural gas 723 750 £20 925 060 1073 1239 1153 1098 t.3 15 2.4 -12 Electricity -35 -142 -114 -23 -56 -115 -135 -246 -270 Gross Inland Consumption 5523 6111 6427 7239 7904 B8QB 3431 9607 Э473 15 2.1 15 05 Solids 1645 1402 1306 1539 1521 170В tsM6 078 1030 -23 15 25 -6-1 Oil 1754 2290 2393 2554 3046 3511 3Ö0E 3606 3434 32 24 2.0 -0.7 Natural gas 703 746 £26 929 084 1073 1239 1153 1098 05 15 23 -12 Nuclear 1102 1245 1226 1618 1557 1557 1557 2004 2004 0.3 2,4 HO 0.4 Electricity -£5 -142 -114 -28 -58 -115 -135 -246 -270 Renewable energy forms 254 571 7ЙВ 787 S55 BS3 1127 1213 1209 125 08 25 12 as % in Gross Inland Consumption Solids 295 22 9 20 3 21 t 10 2 20.4 2D0 102 11.0 Oil 315 37.5 37.2 35.0 38.5 39.0 38.2 37.5 36.2 Natural gas T3.B 12.2 125 127 12.5 12.2 13.1 125 115 Nuclear 21 в 20.4 19.1 20.8 10-7 17,7 165 30.2 30.7 Renewable елегду forms 4. Б 9.3 123 108 10-6 11.2 11.9 12-6 13.4 Gross Electricity Generation in GWha 12440 12652 13622 15114 16193 18404 201 SB 22179 22930 05 1.7 22 1-3 Self consumption and grid losses 1584 1497 1662 1943 1965 2244 2385 2400 2804 05 1.7 2.0 1-6 Fuel Inputs for Thermal Power Generation 1543 1523 1342 1507 1622 19S7 2246 1272 134S -15 15 3.3 -55 Solids 1206 13T5 1253 1411 1431 1702 1849 866 959 -0.3 13 2.6 -6.4 Oil (including refney gas) 155 110 12 9 2 7 2 6 5 -225 -15.5 -05 105 Gas 02 90 62 58 147 165 274 232 235 -35 00 6.4 -16 Biomass & Waste 0 0 15 30 42 114 120 148 151 105 11.1 23 Geotfcermal heat 0 0 0 0 0 □ 0 0 0 Hydrogen - Methanol 0 D 0 0 0 D G 0 0 Fuel Input in other transformation proc. 596 582 253 90 93 175 225 315 343 -82 55 92 4.3 Refineries 542 505 170 1 1 1 1 1 1 -115 -3B.0 15 -0.4 В io'Viete and hydrogen production 0 0 0 D 30 106 173 212 238 16.0 3-3 District heating 53 7B S3 ее 53 68 50 102 103 4.7 -45 -0.5 74 Others 1 1 а 0 0 D 0 a 0 Energy Branch Consumption 122 121 112 104 112 131 +37 13J 166 -09 00 2.1 1.9 Non-Energy Uses 6 122 23В 310 351 406 446 465 468 435 4.0 2.4 C-5 Final Energy Demand 3373 3948 4440' 4892 5448 6167 6597 6576 6393 2.8 2.1 15 -C.3 industry 1460 T190 1424 1057 1693 1835 1977 1908 1337 -03 1-7 1.6 -0.7 - energy intensive industries 720 5Я7 840 103S 1046 1140 124Й 1201 1152 14 22 15 -05 - other industriai sectors 740 593 5S5 619 647 686 730 707 085 -23 1.0 12 -0.6 Residential B53 ПВО 1124 мае 1205 1305 1355 1371 1305 25 0.7 Ш 0.1 Terfaiy 122 259 530 575 569 604 610 609 593 105 -02 D.7 -0.3 Transport 030 1329 1312 1475 1081 2423 2655 2688 2598 35 42 35 -02 by fuel Solids 243 115 07 80 60 63 63 60 52 -85 -4.7 0.5 -15 Oil 1513 2106 2239 2404 2857 3283 3450 3334 3153 45 25 15 -0.0 Gas 603 463 566 665 655 605 753 679 030 -0.0 1.4 1.4 -15 Electricity B37 307 905 1006 »153 1263 1332 1441 1447 05 2.5 15 D-5 Heat (from С HP and District Heating) "" 177 102 105 100 257 363 336 422 434 t5 2.B 2.7 25 Renewable energy forms 0 200 435 452 456 500 012 640 075 0.7 28 ID Otftec 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 11.9 D5 RES in Gross Final Energy Consumption ,ep 768 810 «32 911 1093 1177 1230 0.8 25 12 TOTAL GHGs Emissions (Mt of С0г eq.) 18.1 is.e 20.1 21-3 24.1 25.6 20.8 18.9 0.3 1.4 15 -3.0 of tftich ETS sectors GHGs emissions 9.0 В5 102 112 7-1 5.7 25 -0.5 COj Emissions (energy related) 132 14.1 14.0 153 16.7 19.3 20. В 16.3 14.4 0.6 15 22 -3.6 Power generaöoniDistrict heating 0-2 62 55 02 04 7.6 8.4 4 4 3.2 -11 1.4 25 -0-1 Energy Branch Ö-1 Ö.1 01 00 00 Q.D DO 00 0.0 -05 InOustiy 2-й LS 23 23 2.2 23 25 2-0 15 -07 -Ò.8 15 -3.1 Residential 1-7 2.1 I-3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.6 1.0 15 -25 1.3 05 -0.7 Tertiary 0-0 0.0 \д 1.0 0.0 1.D P-9 0.9 0.9 475 -0.1 -0.1 -1.0 Transport 2.7 3.9 35 4.3 5.6 6.0 7.4 7-4 7.0 35 43 25 -0.5 CO.- Emissions (non energy related) 0.9 0.9 1Л 1-1 1Д 1.4 1J 1.4 -19 15 2.1 02 Non-C02 GHGs Emissions 3.9 3,7 3.5 35 3.4 3.2 3-1 -04 5.6 -0.1 -15 TOTAL GHGs Emissions Index 0990=100) 100.0 102-в 110 8 117-6 133.1 141.2 115.1 104.4 1 SUMMARY ENERGY BALANCE ANO INDICATORS (B) Slovenia: Base luvt 2WJ9 1 1ЭЭ0 i 39 5 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 -Э0--00 'ОО-ЧО 40-20 "20-30 Annual as % of GDP 20.0 270.7 2.30 «Л 315.3 2.30 20.7 254.2 2.18 52.0 2.034 32.7 241.0 2.12 63.0 2.053 36.4 220.5 2.20 54.5 62 2.058 44.0 214.3 2-20 55.4 7-0 2.047 40.2 2.023 50.7 180.fi 1.52 48.2 0.2 -OJ -0.0 Energy intensity indicators Industry (Energy cr\ Value attedi 100. i юе.е 1G0.G 92.4 82.7 70.3 73.2 07.1 63.0 -0.0 -1.9 -t2 -1.4 Residential irnergy wi Pstvale Irwwrie; 00.0 123.5 ICD.D 02.2 852 70.3 71.5 05.3 60.7 0.1 -1.0 -S.0 Tertiary (Energy op WaliR added;. 27.0 54.1 100.0 02.4 72.6 65.0 £7 1 51,3 47.0 137 -32 -2.4 -1.0 Passenger transport (toe/Wpkm) 33.4 45.5 38.5 32.0 32.1 312 30-3 27.5 24.0 1.4 -1.8 -0.0 -2.1 Freight transport ftoe'Mtkm) 22.8 50.0 42.7 41.0 40 1 47.0 452 43.2 40.0 0.5 D.a -02 -1-1 Carbon Intensity indicators Electricity and Steam production rt of CO JMWh} Final energy demand (t of CO^.'toe l Industry Residential Tertiary Transport_ 0.42 0.41 0.34 D-34 D.32 D.32 0.34 o.i a 0.11 -2.0 -0.7 0.5 -iQ.a 2.0S 1.» 1.80 i.es 1 00 1.91 1.88 1.81 1-75 -0.8 0.0 -0.1 -0.7 1.72 1.55 1.65 1.30 1.28 1.23 125 1.06 O.&S -0.4 -2.5 -03 -2.4 1.93 1.81 1-17 1.21 124 1.23 1 10 1.14 1.11 -5.2 0.6 -0.4 -0.7 0-17 0.13 1.65 1.7B 1.66 1.64 1.54 1.49 1.44 25.7 0.0 -О-В -0.7 2.68 2.91 3.80 2.04 2-01 2.85 2-78 2.74 2.70 0.0 0.1 -0.4 -0.3 Indicators for renewable« (excluding industrial waste] fS) ra RES in gross final enetgy demand (X) 10.7 15 В 14.7 142 15.0 17-2 18.4 RES in transport (%) 05 0.3 2.3 4.7 3-B 83 0.6 Gross Electricity generation by fuel type fin GWhl 13622 T5114 16193 18404 20168 22179 22930 1.7 2.2 1.3 Nuclear energy 4760 5383 6035 6035 0035 12480 124Ö0 2.4 0.0 7-5 Coal and lignite 4630 5314 5179 0733 7501 3132 3777 1.1 3.8 -6.6 Petroleum products 40 34 0 19 В t* 13 -14.0 -08 4.0 Gas {including derived gases! 313 324 369 897 1604 1281 1300 IDI 03 -2.0 Biomass & waste 45 loa 171 529 555 645 650 143 12-5 1.7 Hydro 3833 3400 3927 4100 4249 4256 4283 D,2 0.8 O.t Wind 0 G □ 69 107 234 270 5.2 Solar, t dal etc. 0 0 3 20 48 S3 135 32.5 10.9 GeothermaÈ and other renewafctes 0 а 0 0 D 0 0 Met Generation Capacity in WW, 2748 JO (И 3293 403Э 3971 Л5Л8 4346 t M 1:9 2 0 Nudear enerav 5B6 608 706 706 706 1515 1515 0.1 0 0 7.9 Renewable enerav 846 063 1041 1175 138В 1506 1623 Z1 25 1-6 Hydro (pumping excluded : S46 963 1038 1079 1147 1149 tlöö Z1 1JJ 0.2 Wind 0 S 0 75 101 207 317 5-2 Solar 0 0 3 21 50 90 140 32.5 10.9 Otte* renewable; [tidat etc.) 0 а 0 0 0 а 0 Thermal power 1206 1424 1547 2158 1877 1527 1707 2.5 2.0 -0.9 of Vilich «generation опта 453 звв 448 614 5В0 649 944 -0.1 2JS 0.9 of wtneh CCS units 0 0 0 D 0 0. 185 So fids fired 948 947 804 1495 1244 070 1030 -0.6 34 -1.8 Gas "Ired 223 446 624 629 552 573 585 10.8 -12 0.6 Oil fired TT IQ 10 10 2 1 1 -5.2 -13-6 -12.0 Biomass-waste fired 17 21 10 27 70 33 83 1.4 152 0.5 Fuel Cells 0 G О а О D D GeotìvsrmaS heat 0 0 а 0 0 0 а Load factor for net electnc capacities 1%) 53.1 52.3 52.8 4S.7 54.5 52.7 50.3 Efficiency SorShermaS electmsty production (%) 322 32.0 33.0 35.4 37.0 34.9 36.7 CHP indicator of electricity from CHP) 12 e .2 12.5 1в;7 19.0 16.0 16.4 CCS indicator (X of electricity from CCS) Q.O o.a 0.0 O.Q 0.0 0.0 8.3 Won fossil fuels in eJectricty generation |%) 63.4 62.5 62.6 55.4 64.8 78.8 778 - nudear 34.0 38. G 373 32.8 29.0 £6.3 54.4 - renewable energy forms and industrial waste 28.5 23.0 25.3 25.9 24.0 23.5 23:3 Passenger transport activity iGpfcm) 21.« 21.4 25.0 26.9 29.5 32J 35.6 37,1 3S.0 tj 1Д 0.7 Public юаа e ran spon 6.5 4.1 3.5 3.1 3-3 35 3-7 3.8 3.S -ел -0.6 1-1 0.4 Private cars and motorcycles 13.5 16.5 20.5 22.7 24-0 27 J 30-1 31.4 32.1 43 2.0 t.0 0.6 Rail 1-4 0.6 0.7 03 0.8 0-9 1-0 1-1 1.1 -6.8 1.7 1.9 1-1 Aviation 0.2 02 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.9 0.7 0.9 ijò 37 4.9 4-7 33 inland navigation ОД 0.0 0.0 0.0 ал OJ} 0.0 0.0 0.0 Freight transport activity |Gtkm) Э.1 ел 82 143 72 a 79 В 3d e 38 6 40.9 -1t 10.6 4-5 1.6 Trucks 4-9 3.3 53 11.0 104 252 29-3 32.5 34.6 а.в 13.Э 47 1-7 Rail 4-2 3.1 2.0 3.2 4.0 4.9 5.5 0.0 0.3 -3.6 3.4 33 1:3 Inland navigation 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Energy demand in transport (ktoe) 930 1329 1312 1475 1981 2423 2655 26S8 259В 35 42 3.0 -0.2 Public road transpori 51 33 27 23 25 29 26 26 25 -6.2 -0.9 03 -02 Private cars and motorcycles 642 018 900 320 802 961 1012 051 850 3.5 -02 1.3 -1.0 Trucks 181 320 316 570 1000 1362 1535 1625 1635 5.8 122 4.4 0.6 Rail 20 20 34 29 35 40 43 42 31 1.4 03 2-1 -a.2 Aviation 2? 20 25 23 20 35 40 44 48 -08 1.6 33 1.9 inland lavigabsn 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 D 0 Source: EU energy trends to 2030 - update 2009 (2010), pp. 114-115. Table A2: Equation summary. VI V2 vs V4 V5 V6 V7 V» \9 VI0 Unit-. KVAR : 1 FRO FRY PREJ FRTD ZRDM ZRDT FRK RDEL" Л. toe 5-5 FRF FRO PFRF FRTD ZRDM ZRDT FRK RDEU di toe 9 6 RSCP PRPDP RRLR CDEP ODEP RVD RDEU RUNR RPSC ni euro 2000 10 crrmac prpdp prce. rrlr prsc КБ qex qdc QEM QIM yrh yee PTH pqrx pqrm yrw YR QWXL QZXI qrdi qrdì YNH yr yrut pqry PQRF ltwe asQ pkrt*yr pqex pqrx pqem pqrm yrkc lylc pqrm yrwc pqrw pqelz pyh PQRM0) "такс TRKC" EX odep rdeu rdeu rrlr yym yrkn svim yrkn svim такс yrkn srni щши yyn такс yrkn svim rdeu yyk yrkn rdel" pqre pqre yrh yrkc pqwe pqwe lyrp runr pqrjv'3) yrkn "yrkc yrkn rdeu pqrm0j redu yyn vrult yrkc yrkn rdeu yrul yrkc yrkn rdeu runr rbnr lap sc aret rdeu dlapsc tyn rbnr ri er соидиырпоа v шеи» 2000 9 m euro 2000 11 prices hoar-per 7 2000=1 index 10 2000=1 indes 10 2000=1 til. Enro per 12 Source: E3ME Manual (2012). Table A3: Baseline assumptions, complete with sources. DATA SOURCES World assumptions 1. Commodity prices - food CE own assumptions - beverages CE own assumptions - agricultural raw materials CE own assumptions - metals CE own assumptions - energy IEA, PRIMES - oil IEA, PRIMES - global inflation CE own assumptions Region specific assumptions 1. Exchange rates DG ECFIN AMECO database over historical, fixed afterwards - euro exchange rates (WREX) - purchasing power standard (WRPX) 2. Interest rates DG ECFIN AMECO database over historical, fixed afterwards - short-term rate (WRSR) - long-term rate (WRLR) 3. Macro variables Not use for E3ME regions (endogenous) forecasts calibrated to PRIMES 2009 projection Historical data stored in databank from Eurostat Other Regions (CE own assumptions + results from E3MG modelling) - GDP (WGDP) - GDP deflator (WHUC) 4. Government consumption (WRSG, Eurostat, Cambridge Econometrics GW01, GW02,GW03) - defence - fixed after last year of historical data - education - fixed after last year of historical data - health - fixed after last year of historical data 5. Fiscal policy DG ECFIN AMECO database, DG TAX AND CUSTOMS "Taxes in Europe" database over historical period, fixed afterwards - taxes on goods and services (WITR) - standard rate on VAT (WSVT) - taxes on income and capital gains (WDTR) - taxes on international trade (WTTR) - subsidies and other transfers to households (WBNR) - social security taxes paid by employees (WSSR) - social security taxes paid by employers (WERS) 6. Population (WRPO, PARI.... PAR6) Eurostat population projections - total population - male/female split - children/working-age/ old-age pensioner split 7. Labor force (LRP1, LRP2) Not use for E3ME regions (endogenous) Historical data stored in databank from Eurostat LFS - male/female participation rates Source: E3ME program. TableA4: Baselineassumptionsfor Sloveni a and the worldin the E3ME model. sloveNb Code tacrpioi 2010 201 20 2 2013 201 2015 201 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 202 2027 202 8 202 2030 urn Efage ate ncd миу jEie^ urn Etagen PPP[notnied) ncd шму pera 138i 138i 1.38i 1.38i 1 38i 138i 1 38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1.38i 1 38i 1.38i 1 38i 1 38i 1.38i Ш Intenetale hoit u [not ned) eicent (Ulli 00l (i 0 Oli 0 Ol Olli M Olli Olli 0» Olli Olli 0» Olli Olli Oll Olli Olli 0» Olli ИШ Interstate ong И eicent 0138 0138 0Ю 0038 0138 003) OK 003) 0138 OK 0138 0138 OK 0138 0138 OK 0138 0138 OK 0138 HGDP11 MTOi GDPliotnied tli BMEiegon) eeti onyetigiowih 1379 1.937 2.li1 3 2l8 3.2l8 3.5l1 3.il1 3.5l1 3.il1 3.il1 3.5l1 3.il1 3.il1 3. l1 3.il1 3.il1 3.5l1 3.il1 3.il1 3. l1 WSUC01MT12 Шоп lui s ed fii BUE igni) ■Dritte ИЯ M T02 Goveinme nti {ending eeti onyetigiowih 1029 1029 102! 102! 1129 102! 112 1029 1029 102 1029 1029 102 1029 1029 102 1029 1029 102 1029 GW01 DEFENCE Government sjend^Deteice hue ottU government i pending 0.0i 00 (Uli OOi 00 Oli 00 Oli Oli 00 Oli Oli 01 Oli Oli 01 Oli Oli 01 Oli GW02 DUCTTOH Government inednflrctiii hue oM government i pending 02li 02l 02li 02li 02l 02li 02l 12li 02lJ 02l 02li 02lJ 02l 02li 02lJ 02l 02lJ 0 2li 02l 02lJ GH03HETL1H Government i{end^Hetl^ hue ot Ш government i pending 029 0297 029 029 0297 029 0297 029 0297 0297 029 0297 0297 029 0297 0297 029 0297 0297 029 IImmffis Its Miect «h^eolduselold i{ending 118l 118 1.18l 1 18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l 1.18l wsvii:i1 TTXVTT Itx: VTT tie 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 02 ЙШ TTXK Iti: Diet tie (igei) 017l 011 017l 017l 017l 017l 017l 017l 011 017l 017l 011 017l 017l 0171 017l 017l 011 017l 017l VTffl1 TTX TETDE ije lp« ihi sedi tte 1.002 1001 1002 1 10(2 111 1002 111 1102 11012 100 1102 11012 100 1102 1102 100 1102 111(2 100 1102 ИМИ SDBS&TETNS Benefit Ptyrnnt taofuge 03ii 03i 03ii 03ii 03i 03ii 03i 03ii 03ii 03i 03ii 03ii 03i 03ii 03ii 03 03ii 03ii 03 03ii USSK01 ss гам, Soc.i ecemployeei' CDnUntin itte 018i 018 018i 0 18i 018 018i 018 018i 0 181 018 018i 0 18i 018 018i 0 181 018 018i 0 181 018 018i WERS01 SS US Soc.iecempbje^1 anSMo itte 013i 013 OHi 013i 013 013i 013 013i 013i 0H 013i 013i 0H 013i 013i 0H 013i 013i 01 013i uspo top irn Poetin ш onyetig^wb 027i 0237 01 019» 0113 01l 0.087 Olii 013 « -003i -0 07 -110 -0138 -0 1i1 -1185 -0208 -0 2^ « -ll 2il >мшнш Po^tjn:iltk Hi lueoM popUtUn 00 007 00 01 017 01 017 01 01 00 01 017 Oli i 0 0i7 01 Olii Olii 01 01i3 'M2 F CHILD Po^ttn:l6mtk 0-1i Itieofiottl popUtUn 00ii (uli 00i OOi 0 0i7 Oli) Oli Oli) i Oli i 0 0i8 Oli Oli Olii 01 0 Oil Oliti 01 01i2 TS3 M WORK TGE Po^ttn:iitk H-H Itieofiottl popih 03i 03J7 03Ji 03il 03J2 03i 03l 03l2 0339 OS 0333 0331 Odü 032 0 32i 0331 0322 0331 031 031' Ml F WORK TGE Po^ton:^mtk 1nl Itieofiottl popUtUn 0339 035 03S 033i 033l 0332 02 032l 0321 031 031 031l 03 0311 031 031 030 0305 031 0303 TJ M OLD Po^ttn:iitk ii+ Itieofiottl popUtUn Olii i Oli OOi! 0 171 007l 0.079 0082 0 idi 0188 0191 019t 0(197 Ой« 0102 0! 010 0109 0Л 011l 'hi F СИ) Popitim Me ii+ Itieofiottl popita 0102 0102 0102 010l 010i 010 01 0113 011i 0Л 0.12 012t OH 012 0H 0H 013l 0137 0H 01l1 JIH M FTffl STI! Ptftiatra ste: mle lui s ed) eicent ot Hewing poltra 0.7i1 0.7i1 07i1 0.7i1 0.7i1 0 7i1 0.7i 0.7i1 0.7i1 0.7i 0.7i1 0.7i1 0.7i 0.7i1 0.7i1 0.7i 0.7i1 0.7i1 0.7i 0.7i1 JIH F PTSTN STTE Ptftiatra itle: ^mJe Ini sedi eicent ot Me wnling рйНи 0.i7i 0Л 0i7J 0.i7i 0.i7 0 i7i 0Л 0.i7 0.i7i 0 .i75 0.i7 0.i7i 0.i75 0.i7 0.i7i 0175 0.i7 0.i7i 0.i75 0.i7 0.i7i Cole tacrpiji it 2010 2011 2012 2013 201 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026 2027 2028 2029 2030 вди) Commodity Pic : Food etionyetigiowll 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 18 1.8 18 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.8 «G02) Commodil^ Pic Beveugei etionyetigiowll вдв) Commdity Pic '.c li I * M l> etionyetigiowll 2. 2.l 2.l 2. 2.l 2l 2. 2l 21 2l 2. 21 2l 2. 2l 2l 2. 2l up Commodil^ Pdc MettiÈ WI^IJÌ etionyetigiowll l.2 l.2 l.2 l.2 l.2 l2 4.2 l2 l.2 l.2 4.2 4.2 l.2 4.2 4.2 l.2 4.2 l.2 вдм) Commdity Pic Eoeigf etionyetigiowll i.929 i.929 i.929 i.929 i.929 Ш i.8i1 i.8i1 i.8i1 l.iii l.iii 4.iii l.iii l.iii 4.iii l.iii l.iii li l02 «p) Commdity Pic Bentoil шиушцшй 22 22 22 227 22 i3i i3i7 i3i i.12i i.12i i.12i i.12i i.12i i.12i i.12i i.12i l.81l l.81l иод Tgegtte (ШШп ш onyetig^wil ource: E3ME program. Table A5: Values of economic, environmental, and energy variables in different scenarios for the period 2011-2030. SCENARIO RECYCLING / YEAR 2(11 2(12 2(13 2(14 2(15 2(16 2(17 2(18 2(19 2(2( 2(21 2(22 2(23 2(24 2(25 2(26 2(27 2(28 2(29 2(3( Green reevemes from a idbon tit baseline scenario / 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 carbon tax of EUR 55perton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) aal 0 144.639 147.335 150.279 153514 154.514 155.882 157.703 159.536 160.94 159.514 158.126 157.011 156.118 155.148 153.213 151.235 149.65 148.493 147.099 Gross domeric product inmDiai of eiro (RGDP) baseline scenario 28749.77 29436.21 30415.7 31443.8 32502.98 33411.88 34355.28 35349.36 36385.24 37449.73 38176.75 38926.43 39697.25 40507.05 41345.79 41865.08 42408.16 42959.87 43502.27 44051.21 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon № 15 per ton of CO2) budget 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34305.07 35300.83 36336.85 37402.58 38133.77 38889.22 39663.53 40473.73 41309.04 41825.57 42374.68 42926.33 43462.15 44009.93 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security cantjjutions 28749.77 294785 30380.23 31450.78 32501.63 3341958 34367.1 35350.45 36384.39 37445.14 38171.98 38916.1 39691.16 40504.11 41344.97 4185834 42407.76 42959.18 43488.57 44029.78 cràni lux of EUR 55perton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employes' social security c otte® 28749.77 2944668 30353.49 31427.92 32481 3339467 34337.66 353263 36362.72 37426.74 38155.76 38906.42 396813 404919 41329.51 41846.16 42394.95 4294481 43476.59 44021.18 cràni lux of EUR 55perton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) luJget,units ' social security c ntMins 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34360.18 35339.48 36378.32 37451.36 38185.97 38932.13 39706.17 40515.79 41349.45 41852.42 42399.23 42950.67 43487.95 44039.86 cràrn lux of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) udget, employers' social secuntycontibjti^ 28749.77 29415.28 30322.49 31386.87 32439.38 33356.36 34328.9 35318.64 36363.46 37433.86 38163.37 38911.42 39684.97 40495.51 41331.45 41843.31 42391.35 42941.27 43476.87 44026.62 Household c munpliai eqneid№ei in imflion of eito (RSC) baseline scenario 16705.19 16945.31 17470.62 18004.52 18550.77 19074.5 19612.02 20159.48 20729.08 21316.29 21789.22 22266.06 22770.05 23289.98 23818.74 24183.24 24543.27 24956.55 25382.57 25810 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19545.53 20096.52 20667.77 21256.98 21732.45 22210.29 22713.19 23230.92 23758.01 24122.45 24495.48 24913.65 25332.61 25754.82 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon № 15 per ton of CO2) wikers' social secuity c nAtions 16705.19 1697557 17477.51 1802234 185592 19085.13 19623.32 20160.12 20731.11 21320.4 21797.08 2226455 22769.02 2328856 23818.11 24170.78 24539.25 24958.42 25376.35 257962 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employes' social security c otte® 16705.19 1694468 17447.24 17989.73 18527.51 19052.41 19590.35 2013239 20703.96 21293.73 217703 2224209 227466 23265.72 23794.24 2415153 24521.36 2493985 25358.64 2577981 cràrn tlx of EUR 55perton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) udge^wAers' social security c ntMins 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19623.81 20164.48 20737.44 21328.23 21803.74 22267.61 22768.59 23287 23817.9 24169.99 24541.67 24960.25 25379.2 25801.98 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) udget, eemiloyers' social security c oritibutio^ 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19595.12 20140.13 20712.34 21300.78 21774.67 22242.68 22744.26 23262.72 23792.73 24149.85 24522.38 24941.19 25360.65 25783.29 Erporl in mUHion of eito (RSX) baseline scenario 16705.19 16945.31 17470.62 18004.52 18550.77 19074.5 19612.02 20159.48 20729.08 21316.29 21789.22 22266.06 22770.05 23289.98 23818.74 24183.24 24543.27 24956.55 25382.57 25810 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon № 15 per ton of CO2) budget 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19545.53 20096.52 20667.77 21256.98 21732.45 22210.29 22713.19 23230.92 23758.01 24122.45 24495.48 24913.65 25332.61 25754.82 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) wikers' social secuity c nAtions 16705.19 1697557 17477.51 1802234 185592 19085.13 19623.32 20160.12 20731.11 21320.4 21797.08 2226455 22769.02 2328856 23818.11 24170.78 24539.25 24958.42 25376.35 257962 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 16705.19 1694468 17447.24 17989.73 18527.51 19052.41 19590.35 2013239 20703.96 21293.73 217703 2224209 227466 23265.72 23794.24 2415153 24521.36 2493985 25358.64 2577981 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19623.81 20164.48 20737.44 21328.23 21803.74 22267.61 22768.59 23287 23817.9 24169.99 24541.67 24960.25 25379.2 25801.98 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social securitycontibutions 16705.19 16891.03 17392.22 17931.52 18477.28 19004.83 19595.12 20140.13 20712.34 21300.78 21774.67 22242.68 22744.26 23262.72 23792.73 24149.85 24522.38 24941.19 25360.65 25783.29 Toti mmfecttm^ mtput in mUHion EUR (QR) baseline scenario 21531.41 22199.45 22996.59 23848.7 24729.97 25510.09 26305 27079.24 27880.9 28705.55 29188.84 30044.5 30518 31034.2 31365.94 31634.17 31984.08 32300.69 32646.13 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 246929 25477.39 26276.24 27861.56 28683.53 29166.47 30035.12 30511.67 31026.06 31348.3 31652.37 32012.02 32319.98 32665.44 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon № 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social secuity cnAtions 21531.41 22229.12 22990.89 2385003 24719.05 2550239 26295.74 27072.12 27872.67 2868884 29167.51 29558.76 3051388 31034.17 3135898 31651.61 32016 32318.01 32659.15 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 21531.41 2221122 22976.19 2383981 24714.27 254959 26284.69 27864.91 2868559 29167.42 2956431 30038.1 3051306 31029.63 3135926 31654.73 3201331 32315.45 3265835 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 246929 25477.39 26288.89 27870.52 28696.19 29179.96 29571.86 30047.22 31034.96 31350.33 31652.39 32008.75 32315.32 3266203 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social securitycontibutions 21531.41 22214.99 22980.56 23826.07 246929 25477.39 26266.32 27043.07 27865.38 28694.51 29175 29566.49 30037.94 30513.28 31029.36 31355.16 31657.81 32011.4 32315.07 32660.95 Enpynen m thuuiuk (YRE) baseline scenario 936.692 950.426 955.094 955.764 958.411 952.612 946.927 938.577 932.254 920.588 913.883 909.383 905.041 901.945 894.97 887.232 880.346 873.976 869.069 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 943.516 935.464 929.486 918.308 911.838 903.398 900.288 893.212 886.057 879.566 873.35 868.53 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social secuity cnAtions 936692 952.573 957562 958.191 960549 954.568 948615 939.884 92634 921.176 914.372 910.114 903019 895.697 888096 881.357 874887 869.867 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 936692 953.847 957565 957.848 959617 953.441 947391 938.413 931928 920258 913.345 909.153 902028 894.562 887215 880.625 874298 869.396 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 945.369 938.196 922.413 915.526 910.96 906.343 902.984 895.451 888.059 881.422 875.185 870.382 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social securitycontibutions 936.692 950.497 953.889 953.042 955.141 949.1 946.645 938.51 932.958 921.709 914.505 909.912 894.496 887.281 880.734 874.513 869.717 Greeeihrnue gas emissionsm CO2 equvalen thuuaik oftons of cirhn baseline scenario 5588.252 5737.804 5874.773 5998.528 6122.417 6186.53 6258.1 6330.867 6398.466 6463.33 6332.618 6210.716 6091.337 5971.548 5854.552 5768.035 5689.808 5612.959 5535.926 5457.153 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6146.05 6218.732 6292.517 6221.624 6089.353 5851.007 5738.6 5651.438 5565.019 5486.641 5416.851 5343.681 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social secuity cnAutiins 5588252 5699.981 5805.95 5914.157 6031337 6086.616 6150.177 6222.895 6224386 6091.057 5966674 5851.668 5740395 5654.128 5568.177 5487.795 5416669 5343.986 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 5588252 5703.375 5806024 5908.469 6024208 6085.302 6154044 6224.437 6222.169 5968397 5851.377 5738.25 5651.396 5567058 5489.025 5417842 5343.073 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6146.645 6223.044 6296.215 6224.478 5969.082 5853.194 5740.442 5653.166 5566.013 5487.111 5417.339 5344.526 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social securitycontibutions 5588.252 5699.225 5801.967 5910.516 6027.753 6082.999 6150.509 6222.179 6289.215 6224.07 5849.961 5651.136 5489.403 5417.561 5342.396 Total dmand for energy mthmuand to e (FRO) baseline scenario 6528.858 6735.286 6929.519 7113.159 7305.409 7421.845 7549.201 7798.161 7916.722 7704.82 7521.981 7359.104 7208.643 7072.313 7047.299 7031.582 7019.494 7007.009 6991.417 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193944 7299.16 7414.321 7541.112 7670.133 7791.199 7571.272 7375.161 7207.594 6933.324 6906.806 6879.445 6864.735 6861.451 6852.784 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) workers' social security contributions 6528858 6680.491 6841556 7011.197 7197.421 7303.375 7420242 7547.516 7795.493 7574.27 7376.883 7208.198 7064.885 6936641 6911.035 6884056 6866.505 6861389 6853.399 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 6528858 6685.019 6841814 7004.185 7188617 7301.797 7425046 7549.017 7669.717 7787.832 7571.796 7378.862 7210618 7064.275 6933.412 6882391 6868.113 6862943 6852.137 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193944 7299.16 7415.302 7546.529 7674.064 7794.156 7574.749 7380.27 7211.954 6935.68 6908.626 6880.418 6865.489 6862.725 6854.685 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 6528.858 6679.237 6836.475 7007.4 7193944 7299.16 7420.551 7545.693 7785.534 7574.371 7383.883 7212.714 7061.986 6930.139 6906.192 6882.481 6868.658 6862.821 6851.513 Average fuel (energy) pice including tares inEURO/toe (PJRT) baseline scenario 3144.918 3140.383 3144.66 3156.688 3174.105 3182.884 3195.34 3212.91 3260.783 3303.043 3347.844 3449.189 3506.829 3552.643 3598.905 3642.847 3684.911 3730.16 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) budget 3144.918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287534 3298.071 3312.47 3330.179 3351.101 3418.701 3464.836 3514.412 3623.994 3719.383 3764.525 3807.132 3853.669 cràrn lux of EUR 55 per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) wikes' social secuity c nAtions 3144918 3255.151 3261.36 3271.114 3288359 3298.943 3312897 3330.404 3351084 3375.115 3417.795 3463.749 3513.401 3622.774 3669.708 3718.03 3805992 3852.584 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) employers' social security contibutions 3144918 3254.813 3261.43 3271.553 3288.754 3298.492 3311932 3329.914 3351.437 3418011 3463.634 3513341 3565.882 3623334 3718387 3763.46 3806219 3853.038 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (ER 15 per ton of CO2) budget, workers' social securitycontributions 3144.918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287534 3298.071 3312.327 3351.871 3376.649 3419.513 3465.23 3514.767 3623.515 3718.494 3763.498 3806.108 3852.698 cràrn tax of EUR 55per ton of carbon (EUR 15 per ton of CO2) budget, employers' social security contibutions 3144918 3255.683 3262.142 3270.724 3287534 3298.071 3311844 3352.208 3376.789 3464.365 3514366 3624048 3670.382 3718387 3763.411 3806358 3853.222 Source: E3ME program and own calculations. Appendix 1: Aggregate demand for energy and its parameters for Slovenia. In Table A6 we show the specification of aggregated demand for energy that is used in the E3ME model. The equation is based on the work of Barker, Ekins and Johnston (1995), Hunt and Manning (1989) and Bentzen and Engsted (1993). »The aggregate energy equation considers the total fuel used (summation of 12 fuel types) in thousand tonnes of oil equivalent (th.toe) by 19 fuel users. The demand for energy by a fuel user is dependent on the ,activity' for the fuel user. This is chosen as gross economic output for most sectors, but household fuel demand is a function of total consumers' expenditure. A restriction is imposed such that as activity increases then demand for energy use will not decline (all other factors being equal). The average price ratio captures the effect of prices relative to the fuel used, and is deflated by unit costs. The equations have been tested so that relative price increases cause demand to fall but relative price decreases have no effect. Such asymmetrical price effects in aggregate energy demand equations have been the subject of other research (Gately, 1993; Walker and Wirl, 1993; Grubb, 1995). The idea is that because energy is used via capital stock with a long lifetime, and since technical change is progressive and is not generally reversed, when energy prices rise and energy savings are introduced, then when energy prices fall again, these savings are not reversed i.e. energy demand responds to rises in real prices, but not falls. The effect changes the properties of the model in a non-linear fashion: if in the base run real energy prices fall over the projection period, then increases in energy taxes will have no effect until they start to increase real prices (one year to the next, not compared to the base). The long-run price elasticity for road fuel is imposed at -0.7 for all regions, also Slovenia, following the research on long-run demand (Franzen and Sterner, 1995) and (Johansson and Schipper, 1997). The measures of research and development expenditure and investment capture the effect of new ways of decreasing energy demand (energy saving technical progress) and the elimination of inefficient technologies, such as energy saving techniques replacing the old inefficient use of energy. Research and development expenditure in industries 16-18 (machinery) and 19 (motor vehicles) for the EU as a whole take into account spillover effects from international companies.« (E3ME Manual, 2012, page 49-50). Tabel A6: Specification of agregate demand for energy. Co-integrating dynamic equation: DLN(FR0(.)) [total fuel used by fuel users] = BFR0(,.1) [constant] + BFR0(.,2) * DLN(FRY(.)) [activity measure] + BFR0(.,3) * DLn(pREN(.)) [average price ratio] + BFR0(.,4) * DLN(FRTD(.)) [R&D by fuel user] + BFR0(.,5) * DLN(ZRDM) [EU R&D in machinery] + BFRü(.,6) * DLn(zRDT) [EU R&D in transport] + BFR0(.,7) * DLn(fRK(.)) [investment by fuel user] + BFR0(.,8) * DRDEU [German unification] + BFR0(.,9) * D09R [2009 recession dummy] + BFR0(.,10) * DLN(FR0(-1)) [lagged changes in fuel use] Co-integrating long- term equation: DLN(FR0(.)) [total fuel used by fuel users] = BFR0(.,11) * ECM(-1) [lagged error correction] + BFR0(,.12) [constant] + BFR0(,.13) * LN(FRY(.)) [activity measure] + BFR0(.,14) * LN(PREN(.)) [average price ratio] + BFR0(.,15) * LN(FRTD(.)) [r&D by fuel user] + BFR0(.,16) * LN(ZRDM) [EU R&D in machinery] + BFR0(.,17) * LN(ZRDT) [EU R&D in transport] + BFR0(.,18) * LN(FRK(.)) [investment by fuel user] + BFR0(.,19) * RDEU [German unification] + BFR0(.,20) * D09R [2009 recession dummy] + ECM [error] Identity: PREN = PFR0(.)/PRYM [average price ratio] Restrictions: BFR0(.,3 .,4 .,5 .,6 .,7 ' .,14 .,15.,16 .,17 .,18) <=0 ['right sign'] BFR0(.,2), BFR0(.,13) >=0 [modeling energy demand/activity ratio] 0>BRF0(.,11)>-1 ['right sign'] Definitions: BFR0 is a matrix of parameters FR0 is a matrix of total fuel used by 22 fuel users for 33 regions, th toe. PREN is a matrix of average price used deflated by unit cost for 33 regions, euro/toe FRY is a matrix of activity for 22 fuel users and 33 regions, m euro at 2005 prices FRTD is R&D in machinery by the EU, m euro at 2005 prices ZRDM is R&D in transport by the EU, m euro at 2005 prices ZRDT is a matrix of investment by 22 fuel users for 33 regions, m euro at 2005 prices FRK is a matrix of prices of value added at market prices for each region (2005 = 1.0, local price) PRYM is a matrix of average prices in euro/tonne of all fuels used by each fuel user PFR0 is a matrix of average prices in euro/tonne of all fuels used by each fuel user RDEU is a dummy matrix for German unification (=0 for other countries) D09R is a dummy matrix for 2009 recession (=0 until 2008, =1 from 2009 onward) (.) indicates that a matrix is defined across sectors LN indicates natural logarithm DLN indicates change in natural logarithm ECM [error] In Table A7 we show the values of estimated paramaters of agregated demand for energy for Slovenia. Tabel A7: Values of parameters of agregated demand for energy function for Slovenia. FUEL USERS 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 COEFF 10 CIENTS 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 1 Power own use & trans. 0.055 0 -0.328 0 -0.456 0 -0.473 0 0 -0.2 -0.95 7.964 0.247 -0.177 0 -0.088 -0.058 -0.027 0 0 2 O.energy own use & tra -0.064 0 0 -0.031 0 -0.64 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 5.337 0.232 -0.331 -0.086 -0.019 -0.056 -0.044 0 0 3 Iron & steel 0.02 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 0 0.6 -0.95 9.106 0.117 -0.263 -0.091 -0.249 -0.037 -0.013 0 0 4 Non-ferrous metals 0.005 0 -0.85 0 0 0 -0.169 0 0 0.095 -0.216 7.931 0.297 -0.311 -0.015 0 -0.184 -0.208 0 0 5 Chemicals 0.008 1.2 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.093 -0.417 7.69 0.432 -0.253 -0.135 -0.073 -0.308 -0.011 0 0 6 Non-metallics nes 0.138 0.06 -0.273 -0.032 0 0 -0.021 0 0 0.01 -0.799 6.685 0.292 -0.279 -0.05 -0.027 -0.132 0 0 0 7 Ore-extra.(non-energy) 0.153 0 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 9.544 0.751 -0.331 0 -0.166 -0.653 -0.026 0 0 8 Food, drink & tob. -0.008 1.2 -1.3 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.936 4.555 0.609 -0.221 -0.003 -0.14 -0.061 -0.251 0 0 9 Tex., cloth. & footw. -0.078 1.2 -0.504 -0.295 -1 0 -0.111 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 7.24 0.546 -0.269 -0.015 -0.049 -0.44 -0.08 0 0 10 Paper & pulp 0.049 0 -1.024 0 0 -1 -0.06 0 0 0.159 -0.2 4.684 0.635 -0.387 -0.005 -0.029 -0.106 -0.091 0 0 11 Engineering etc 0.065 0 -0.871 0 -1 0 -0.27 0 0 0.134 -0.2 6.39 0.406 -0.214 -0.005 -0.162 -0.155 -0.04 0 0 12 Other industry 0.076 0 0 0 0 0 -1.56 0 0 0.228 -0.95 12.476 0.709 -0.492 -0.02 -0.512 -0.278 -0.358 0 0 13 Rail transport -0.042 0.844 -0.344 0 0 0 -0.024 0 0 -0.2 -0.723 5.764 0.19 -0.212 0 -0.136 -0.043 -0.016 0 0 14 Road transport -0.107 0 -0.095 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.454 -0.574 6.184 0.602 -0.7 0 0 -0.021 -0.008 0 0 15 Air transport 0.035 0 0 0 0 0 -0.013 0 0 0.249 -0.2 5.399 0.457 -0.403 0 -0.174 0 -0.065 0 0 16 Other transp. serv. 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.146 -0.359 0 -0.08 -0.38 -0.327 0 0 17 Households -0.004 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 3.875 0.718 -0.217 0 -0.026 -0.072 -0.258 0 0 18 Other final use 0.362 0 -0.91 -0.228 0 0 -3 0 0 0.6 -0.95 5.73 0.666 -0.248 -0.049 -0.085 -0.038 -0.361 0 0 19 Non-energy use 0.124 0 -0.681 0 -1 0 0 0 0 -0.2 -0.2 7.721 0 -0.221 0 -0.003 -0.133 0 0 0 Source: E3ME model. The price elasticities of energy demand for fuel users are for example shown in column 3 and 14. Column 3 shows price elasticites of demand based on co-integrating dynamic equation, while column 14 shows long term elasticites of demand based on co-integrating long-term equation.. For example, 1% increase of average price ratio (variable PREN) causes decrease in quantity demanded for energy in road transportation for 0.7%. THE RELEVANCE OF EMPLOYEE-RELATED RATIOS FOR EARLY DETECTION OF CORPORATE CRISES MARIO SITUM1 Received: 7 February 2014 Accepted: 27 January 2015 ABSTRACT: The purpose of this study was to analyse whether employee-related ratios derived from accounts have incremental predictive power for the early detection of corporate crises and bankruptcies. Based on the literature reviewed, it can be seen that not much attention has been drawn to this task, indicating that further research is justified. For empirical research purposes, a database of Austrian companies was used for the time period 2003 to 2005 in order to develop multivariate linear discriminant functions for the classification of companies into the two states; bankrupt and non-bankrupt, and to detect the contribution of employee-related ratios in explaining why firms fail. Several ratios from prior research were used as potential predictors. In addition, other separate ratios were analysed, including employee-related figures. The results of the study show that while employee-related ratios cannot contribute to an improvement in the classification performance of prediction models, signs of these ratios within the discriminant functions did show the expected directions. Efficient usage of employees seems to play an important role in decreasing the probability of insolvency. Additionally, two employee-related ratios were found which can be used as proxies for the size of the firm. This had not been identified in prior studies for this factor. Keywords: bankruptcy prediction, crisis indicators, discriminant analysis, ratio analysis JEL Classification: C12, C38, G33 1. INTRODUCTION Fast-changing environmental conditions increase the challenges faced by enterprises to remain successful in today's markets. The insolvency statistics for Europe show that after the start of financial crisis in 2007/2008, insolvency rates increased and the situation continued to deteriorate thereafter. Nevertheless, the problem of business failures and the potential for insolvency is still an interesting topic within management science, as the damages on a macroeconomic level are significant. Therefore, it is both necessary and useful to direct research towards the early prediction of corporate crises and financial distress. It is generally accepted that prediction models should recognize potential economic and 1 University of Applied Sciences, Fachhochschule Kufstein Tirol Bildungs GmbH, Kufstein, Austria; e-mail: mario. situm@fh-kufstein.ac.at financial difficulties as early as possible. The best timing for the detection of crisis is at the strategic crisis stage, which is in practice very difficult to detect, due to the weak signals apparent during this stage (Pretorius, 2008, p. 416; Exler & Situm, 2013, p. 162). This type of crisis is not fully visible in financial statement figures and other non-financial ratios are therefore needed, such as market-based indicators and macroeconomic variables, to make them visible and to achieve stronger and more reliable early warning signals. If this is possible, sufficient time will then remain to induce turnaround activities, which are less costly and far more efficient than in the later stages of crisis. Even if it is currently recognized that a properly functioning forecasting tool should include a combination of the aforementioned variables (Grunert, Norden & Weber, 2006; Altman, Sabato & Wilson, 2010; Madrid-Guijarro, Garcia-Perez-de-Lema & van Auken, 2011; Iazzolino, Migliano & Gregorace, 2013), the relevance of figures from financial statements as discriminating variables between failed and non-failed firms remains prominent. This paper focuses on this aspect and devotes special attention to accounting ratios related to employee data. An extensive review of 238 papers dealing with the search for potential variables for the differentiation between the two types of firms revealed that such ratios have not received much attention in this field of study. Therefore, within this research, several ratios related to employees from prior research and several new ratios not found to be analysed in the past were tested to assess their ability to act as prediction variables. An analysis was made based on a database including accounting figures of Austrian firms for the years 2003 and 2004. The aim was to explore how solvent and insolvent firms differ in such ratios and whether the performance of insolvency prediction models based on multivariate linear discriminant analysis could be improved, when these ratios are included with traditional accounting ratios already known as prediction variables. It was found that several employee-related variables showed discriminatory power between the two types of firms. Nevertheless, this ability could not be exploited to attain improved classification results. Despite this, signs of the variables indicated a direction which was consistent with expectations and can be interpreted economically. Summarized, it can be said that employee-related variables carry certain information which is relevant for discrimination between failed and non-failed firms, but their predictive power is somehow limited and therefore not sufficient in order to be included into a well-functioning forecasting model for bankruptcies. This paper is organized as follows: First, a literature review is given about the origins of using accounting ratios for the prediction of insolvencies. This is followed by some insights into more recent research, where results concerning the usage of non-financial indicators within bankruptcy prediction are summarized. Additionally, some relevant papers are highlighted with reference to their main conclusions, where employee-related ratios were investigated concerning predictability. Second, three research hypotheses and three research questions are then presented. Third, a description about the database and the selection of samples for empirical tests is given. Fourth, a presentation about the ratios applied within this work is provided, where some of them are based on literature review and some were not found to be used in previous studies. Fifth, the statistical analyses and results are presented, which are necessary to extract the most relevant variables for the construction of an insolvency prediction model. Sixth, the equations obtained for multivariate linear discriminant functions for the different years and combinations of ratios including their performance quality are presented. Seventh, the main conclusions of the result are summarized. At last, implications and limitations of the study are described, and recommendations for future research are given. Within this section the research hypotheses are tested and the research questions are answered. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Numerous research papers can be found in the field of business failure prediction which extracted a number of differing variables which are suitable for the prediction of business failures and bankruptcies. The most prominent variables are accounting ratios, which were derived from the financial statements of companies. Early research stated that accounting ratios show the potential to differentiate between bankrupt and non-bankrupt firms (Beaver, 1966; Altman, 1968). Several other papers confirmed these findings based on empirical results (Altman, Haldeman & Narayanan, 1977; Dambolena & Khoury, 1980; Zmijewski, 1984; Casey & Bartczak, 1985; Chalos, 1985; Gombola, Haskins, Ketz & Williams, 1987; Gilbert, Menon & Schwartz, 1990; Platt, Platt & Pedersen, 1994; McKee, 1995; Foster, Ward & Woodroof, 1998; Doumpos & Zopounidis, 1998). Further research concluded that prediction models using only accounting ratios are inferior to models which combine accounting ratios with other financial and non-financial ratios. Financial ratios could comprise data not available from financial statements and replicate market data of e.g. stock prices, stock volatilities etc. Non-financial ratios can include factors such as management quality or efficiency, which are not directly observable, but can be estimated by appropriate quantitative measures. It is currently generally accepted that insolvency prediction models should include a mix of accounting, financial and non-financial variables as the accuracy of prediction can be increased in contrast to models including only accounting ratios (Thornhill & Amit, 2003; Grunert, Norden & Weber, 2006; Altman, Sabato & Wilson, 2010; Madrid-Guijarro, Garcia-Perez-de-Lema & van Auken, 2011; Iazzolino, Migliano & Gregorace, 2013). The study by Thornhill & Amit (2003) found that deficiencies in general and financial management can be used as variables to explain why younger firms are more likely to fail. For older firms, failure is more dependent on external forces. A similar conclusion was made by Grunert, Norden & Weber (2006), where the factor of management quality displayed statistical significance to such an extent that this non-financial variable contributed to an improved classification. Furthermore, this research found in general that models incorporating financial and non-financial factors lead to significantly more accurate default probabilities than the single use of either financial or non-financial factors. This result was confirmed by the study of Altman, Sabato & Wilson (2010), where the inclusion of non-accounting data to the basic z-score model significantly improved classification performance. This study concluded that needing a longer time to file accounts after the year end is associated with a higher probability of difficulties. It was also stated that firms which have an audit qualification are more prone to failure, based on the indication that the long-term viability is in some doubt. The study of Madrid-Guijarro, Garcia-Perez-de-Lema & van Auken (2011) analysed factors affecting the external and internal environment of the firm and their impact on financial distress. They showed that high competition among existing firms in the industry and high bargaining power of customers increase the probability of distress. A higher technological level was negatively associated with bankruptcy. The overall conclusion of the study was that some strategic variables have a close association with financial distress. Iaz-zolino, Migliano & Gregorace (2013) investigated the contribution of intellectual capital (human capital, structural capital, relational capital) for the purposes of aiding prediction. Intellectual capital showed a contribution for credit risk decisions and was useful for the classification of defaulted and non-defaulted firms. The general conclusion followed that of the aforementioned studies, namely that a scoring model should include financial and non-financial information in order to improve prediction accuracy and model quality. The inclusion of employee-related ratios - these are ratios where certain variables concerning employees and their associated costs (e.g. number of employees, ln(number of employees), sales/number of employees, EBIT/employee costs etc.) are considered - was not analysed extensively within research. The review of 238 papers related to the task of crises and insolvency prediction revealed that only in a few studies were such ratios included in the starting base (i.e. a catalogue of potential explanatory variables), but hardly any of these were detected as having discriminatory power to divide between failed and non-failed firms. In situations of financial distress or crisis, entrepreneurs try to improve the company's results through various measures, and cost cutting seems to be one of the most effective measures undertaken in this regard. Firms which recovered from crisis had improved their operating performance through cost rationalization, lay-offs, closures and the integration of business units (Sudarsanam & Lai, 2001; Pretorius, 2008). Unsuccessful enterprises are mostly unable to exploit these opportunities due to different circumstances. This includes the inability to efficiently use employee resources. The professional and economic use of staff seems important for corporate success and it also depends on management qualities as to how well these aspects are fulfilled. It is possible for companies to increase EBIT via tight control of labor costs (Kim & Gu, 2006). Therefore, ratios associated and related to employee-figures could be seen as a measurement of management efficiency. It is worth attempting to analyse this aspect by using employee-related ratios from prior research, but also with some new ratios which have not been used as potential explanatory variables in previous studies. Before this, some results from papers are presented where employee-related ratios were considered, where differing results were obtained concerning their suitability as predictors for insolvencies and crises. Bruse (1978) conducted one of the first studies which considered employees for the prediction of the potential growth of a company. He explicitly analysed growing and non- growing firms in Germany and developed a model that was able to distinguish between these two types of firms. The ratios sales/number of employees and staff costs/sales can be found within his starting catalogue. Only the second ratio showed the ability to forecast corporate growth alongside ratios of liquidity and turnover. Within the work of Gebhardt (1980), three employee-related ratios were defined as starting variables. These were staff costs/sum of costs, staff costs/revenues and value added/staff costs. None of these variables displayed statistical significance within univariate and multivariate analyses and were therefore not considered to act as predictors to distinguish between failed and non-failed firms. Wilson, Chong & Peel (1995) analysed the ability of the ratio of directors remuneration/ employee remuneration to act as a discriminatory variable within a logistic model for the distinction between failed and distressed acquired firms. The resulting negative sign signifies that the more directors earn relative to staff, the more likely it is that a firm can be assigned as distressed acquired. No specific explanation was given within their work for this occurrence. Within the studies of Lennox (1999a and 1999b), the number of employees appeared as a relevant variable for discrimination between failed and non-failed firms. This ratio can be seen as a proxy for the size of the firm. Small firms and indirectly, firms with a low number of employees, are more likely to fail. This aspect confirms results from studies before and after Lennox, where the size of the firm played a crucial role for discrimination between bankrupt and non-bankrupt firms, even if size was sometimes measured by using different variables (Altman, Haldeman & Narayanan, 1977; Ohlson, 1980; Theodossiou, Kahya, Saidi & Phillipatos, 1996; Dawley, Hoffman & Brockman, 2003; Bhattarcharjee, Higson, Holly & Kattuman, 2009; Chancharat, Tian, Davy, McCrae & Lodh, 2010; Pervan & Visic, 2012; Situm, 2014). Within the work of Whitaker (1999), a more complex ratio was constructed for the prediction of a company's recovery from financial distress. The ratio was defined as number of employees/total assets (following year)/number of employees/total assets (pre-distress year). A decrease in the number of employees can help firms to recover and can therefore provide valuable signals concerning the economic health of a firm. Gudmundsson (2002) investigated the potential role of specific variables for the prediction of bankruptcy in the airline industry. Three non-financial ratios were included in the analyses: Number of pilots per aircraft, number of employees per aircraft and number of hours flown per pilot. Only the second variable showed statistical significance with a positive sign. This meant that non-distressed airlines exhibited a lower value compared to distressed ones. The fewer employees used per aircraft in action, the lower the probability of failure. Neves & Vieira (2004) found that the ratio percentage of value added for employees and value added per employee were explanatory variables for the discrimination between bankrupt and non-bankrupt companies. The second variable was one of the most significant signals for financial distress. Distressed firms showed much lower values for value added compared to non-distressed firms. The ability of this variable to act as a predictor was also found within the studies of Nam, Kim, Park & Lee (2008) and Lin, Wang, Wu & Chuang (2009). Yim & Mitchell (2007) analysed the ratio of sales/employees within their study to distinguish between failed and non-failed firms in the financial industry. It showed no significance and therefore did not appear as a predictor within their forecasting model. Nam, Kim, Park & Lee (2008) used the growth rate of added value/employee as a potential variable and recognized that it does not have any discriminatory power. Wetter and Wennberg (2009) analysed the effect of human and social capital on a firm's performance and the ability of related measures to assist in the prediction of bankruptcies. Their conclusion was that these factors have the discriminatory power to divide between successful and unsuccessful firms. Bartual, Garcia, Gimenez & Romero-Civera (2012) began their analyses with two employee-related variables: sales/personnel expenses and sales/financial expenses + personnel expenses). Only the second variable was statistically significant and therefore suitable to discriminate between failed and non-failed firms. Firms exhibiting a higher value of this ratio are more stable and therefore less vulnerable to problems. Resistance against crises and bankruptcies can be optimized by an increase in sales and the reduction of personnel expenses. In summary, it can be concluded that the focus in research on employee-related ratios within business failure and insolvency prediction is relatively low when compared to the numerous studies conducted in this field. Due to this lack of analysis concerning these ratios as potential predictors, it is interesting and useful to conduct a separate study where some of the existing, but also some new, as-yet unanalysed ratios is investigated, which were not considered within prior research. From reviewing the literature, it can be expected that some variables will show discrimination ability whereas others will not. This will be the main task of this paper, but also attention will be given to the contribution of each variable concerning the identification of the corporate economic situation. 3. RESEARCH HYPOTHSES AND QUESTIONS Based on the findings from previous literature, it seems that some financial statement figures and other employee-related ratios have a certain explanatory power for the event of bankruptcy. Firms in financial distress need to implement turnaround activities in order to recover. Employees are a cost factor affecting financial statement figures and it is generally possible from a practical viewpoint to improve different ratios through a reduction of the costs associated with employees. Generally, it is expected that firms with an ineffective use of employees and high staff costs are more likely to become bankrupt. H1: The higher the proportion between staff costs to sales, the higher the probability of insolvency. H2: When employee-related ratios are added to prediction models with "traditional" accounting ratios, then the prediction performance of such models can be improved. H3: The number of employees and associated ratios with the number of employees are potential proxies for the size of the firm. The third hypothesis is of relevance due to prior studies, where the variable number of employees and ln(number of employees) were found to be proxies for the size of the firm. In previous research, attempts to find other proxies for the size of the firm associated with the number of employees were not made, with the result that this approach is something new in comparison to prior research. Additionally, several research questions shall be answered with the empirical data of this study. First, how can employee-related ratios contribute to early detection of corporate crises and bankruptcies? Second, which of the employee-related ratios are potential predictors for the construction of a business failure prediction model? Last, can the inclusion of such factors be helpful to improve the prediction accuracy of an insolvency prediction model? 4. DATABASE The database for this study consists of Austrian companies divided into the categories bankrupt and non-bankrupt. The observation period ranges from the years 2003 to 2004. The selected firms were not matched pairwise, as in many other previous studies due to several problems with this selection technique. An attempt was made to obtain a sample which is representative of the whole population. Thomas, Edelman and Crook (2002) propose such an approach. Nevertheless, this procedure also provides problems in terms of statistical estimation. If too few bankrupt firms are present in the sample, then their proportion is underestimated and developed models are much better at detecting non-bankrupt firms. First, a random initial sample was selected for the observation period. Here, 17 bankrupt firms were found from a database for the period 2003 and 2004. Then a random sample of non-bankrupt firms was chosen for the same period for 170 companies. Therefore, the proportion between non-bankrupt and bankrupt firms is 10:1. Similar proportions had also been used within different prior studies (Baetge, Beuter & Feidicker, 1992; Begley, Ming & Watts, 1996; Lennox, 1999a; Lennox, 1999b; Shah & Murtaza, 2000; Paradi, Asmild & Simak, 2004; Hol, 2007; Iazzolino, Migliano & Gregorace, 2013; Chaudhuri, 2013) Second, a random test sample was obtained in order to assess the performance of the developed models and their ability to be used for practical purposes. Here, 10 bankrupt and 100 non-bankrupt firms were chosen randomly. The composition of the firms within the different samples is presented in table 1. Table 1: Composition of firms in initial and validation samples 2003 2004 [two years prior to [one year prior to bankruptcy] bankruptcy] Bankrupt Non-bankrupt Bankrupt Non-bankrupt initial sample 17 170 17 170 test sample 10 100 10 100 5. METHODOLOGY AND RESEARCH DESIGN In order to test the research hypotheses and research questions, different statistical tests and applications were applied within this study. First, descriptive statistics for the bankrupt and non-bankrupt companies were computed. Second, a test for normality based on Kolmogorov-Smirnov was applied, in order to determine whether the selected ratios were normally distributed. Normally distributed data are an important theoretical pre-condition for the application of multivariate linear discriminant analysis. Third, the differences in means, medians and variances for the two groups were analysed, in order to detect whether there are differences between the two groups in the variables. This analysis shall determine which of the variables are the most effective for discriminating between bankrupt and non-bankrupt companies. Fourth, a correlation analysis was computed to recognize how the variables are correlated with each other. This application was complemented by a factor analysis, where the loadings of the variables to certain factors were determined. Last, multivariate linear discriminant functions were computed which are suitable to divide a posteriori between failed and non-failed companies two years and one year prior to the event of bankruptcy. In order to test the incremental informational content of employee-related ratios, three types of functions were computed for this purpose. These are functions containing only traditional ratios, only employee-related ratios and a combination of both. The validity of the models was then tested with the companies from the test group. The quality and accuracy of the models was evaluated using appropriate performance measures. 6. SELECTION OF VARIABLES The variables for the purpose of this study were selected based on their appearance in previous literature. As already stated in this paper, variables related to employees have not been extensively analysed in prior studies. Some traditional ratios and some employee-related were therefore selected. Following accounting variables appeared relatively often in previous studies: • Total Equity/Total Assets (Laitinen & Laitinen, 2000; Grunert, Norden & Weber, 2005; Pompe & Bilderbeek, 2005; Shin, Lee & Kim, 2005; Min & Lee, 2005, Muller, Steyn-Bruwer & Hamman, 2009; Bartual, Garcia, Gimenez & Romero-Civera, 2012) • Total Debt/Total Assets (Ohlson, 1980; Zmijewski, 1984; Frydman, Altman & Kao, 1985; Pacey & Pham, 1990; Bryant, 1997; Doumpos & Zopounidis, 1998; Andandarajan, Lee & Anandarajan, 2001; Brabazon & Keenan, 2004; Neves & Vieira, 2006; Pervan & Kuvek, 2013; Chaud-huri, 2013). • EBIT/Total Assets (Altman, 1968; Gilbert, Menon & Schwartz, 1990; Coats & Fant, 1993; Altman & Saunders, 1998; Grunert, Norden & Weber, 2005; Chen, Marshall, Zhang & Ganesh, 2006; Li & Sun, 2011; Bartual, Garcia, Gimenez & Romero-Civera, 2012; Iazzolino, Migliano & Gregorace, 2013) • Ln(Total Assets) (Ohlson, 1980; Frydman, Altman & Kao, 1985; Barniv & Raveh, 1989; Whitaker, 1999; Chi & Tang, 2006; Pervan & Visic, 2012, Situm, 2014) • Ln(Sales) (Chancharat, Tian, Davy, McCrae & Lodh, 2010; Situm, 2014) Additionally, the following ratios were included within this study which were derived partly from previous literature. Also displayed are new ratios which have not been analysed in this form within prior research. Several of them contain figures related to employees. Table 2: Additional ratios for analysis Ratios on the right side are defined as "new", because these ratios were not found to be considered as potential prediction variables based on an extensive literature review of 238 papers related to the topic of crisis- and insolvency prediction Ratios found in previous research "new" ratios not found to be used in previous research Sales/Total Assets [Altman, 1968; Brabazon & Keenan, 2004; Dietrich, Arcelus & Srinivasan, 2005; Bartual, Garcia, Gimenez & Romero_Civera, 2012; Tsai, 2013]_ Ln(Sales/Total Assets) Ln(Number of Employees) [Situm, 2014] Staff Costs/Sales [Bruse, 1978; Gebhardt, 1980] Ln(Sales/Number of Employees) Ln(Staff Costs/Number of Employees) EBIT/Sales [Marchesini, Perdue & Bryan, 2005] EBITDA/Staff Costs Sales/Staff Costs [inverse relation to the ratio staff costs/sales based on Bruse, 1978; Gebhardt, 1980] EBIT/Staff Costs 7. STATISTICAL ANALYSES 7.1 Descriptive statistics Table 3 provides the means, medians and standard deviations for the chosen variables for two years and one year prior to bankruptcy. The mean of total equity/total assets deteriorated for bankrupt firms from 2003 to 2004, which indicates that bankrupt firms incur additional losses as insolvency approaches. Firms in financial trouble are financing their operating business with liabilities, with the result that they are exhibiting much higher leverage ratios in mean and median than solvent firms. Ln(sales), ln(number of employees) and ln(total assets) are all measures associated with the size of the firm. All three variables showed higher means for the solvent firms in comparison to the bankrupt firms for the two observation periods. This indicates that bankrupt firms are in mean, but also in median, smaller than non-bankrupt ones. Staff costs/sales are much lower for solvent firms in mean, which indicates that employee-resources are used more efficiently by financially healthy companies. Higher efficiency of non-bankrupt firms can also be argued by the ratios EBITDA/staff costs, EBIT/staff costs and EBIT/Sales. These variables showed in mean and in median higher values for non-bankrupt than for bankrupt firms. Table 3: Descriptive statistics 2003 2004 [two years prior to bankruptcy] [one year prior to bankruptcy] Ratio Class Mean Median Stand.-Dev. Mean Median Stand.-Dev. Total Equity/ 0 -0.062 0.056 0.549 -0.851 -0.330 1.468 Total Assets 1 0.153 0.177 0.510 0.223 0.193 0.295 Total Debt/ 0 1.062 0.944 0.549 1.851 1.330 1.468 Total Assets 1 0.848 0.823 0.510 0.777 0.807 0.295 Sales/Total 0 2.492 1.694 2.492 1.832 1.238 2.068 Assets 1 1.800 1.386 1.527 1.693 1.301 1.485 ln(Sales/Total 0 0.225 0.527 1.777 -0.007 0.214 1.271 Assets) 1 0.143 0.326 1.171 0.088 0.263 1.102 ln(Sales) 0 11.221 11.235 1.412 11.390 11.549 1.100 1 12.071 11.988 1.243 12.237 12.031 1.205 ln(Number of 0 3.418 3.689 1.175 2.687 2.639 1.309 Employees) 1 3.834 4.025 1.715 3.749 3.912 1.537 ln(Sales/ 0 11.221 11.235 1.412 11.390 11.549 1.100 Number of Employees) 1 12.071 11.988 1.243 12.237 12.031 1.205 ln(Staff 0 10.346 10.409 0.542 10.481 10.627 0.591 Costs/ Number of Employees) 1 10.676 10.681 0.726 10.690 10.686 0.615 Staff Costs/ 0 3.736 0.325 13.810 0.840 0.367 1.500 Sales 1 0.430 0.274 0.843 0.347 0.262 0.474 Sales/Staff 0 4.188 3.076 4.444 4.198 2.728 6.051 Costs 1 7.130 3.653 11.442 11.982 3.817 34.833 EBITDA/ 0 -0.152 0.107 1.288 -0.503 -0.230 1.514 Staff Costs 1 0.509 0.221 1.571 1.184 0.324 4.072 EBIT/Staff 0 -0.251 0.036 1.284 -0.695 -0.312 1.463 Costs 1 0.021 0.102 2.070 0.770 0.162 3.354 EBIT/Sales 0 -17.311 0.017 71.301 -1.507 -0.058 4.217 1 -1.254 0.027 15.052 0.043 0.033 0.291 2003 [two years prior to bankruptcy] 2004 [one year prior to bankruptcy] Ratio Class Mean Median Stand.-Dev. Mean Median Stand.-Dev. EBIT/Total 0 -0.077 0.024 0.292 -0.531 -0.040 0.994 Assets 1 -0.048 0.034 0.909 0.056 0.045 0.163 ln(Total 0 14.415 14.831 1.126 14.084 14.735 1.783 Assets) 1 15.762 15.743 1.807 15.898 15.735 1.742 7.2 Test for normality of data The test of normality based on Kolmogorov-Smirnov at the 5 percent level is reported in Table 4. Normality of data cannot be assumed for the majority of the variables. The only variable which showed normality for both groups and for both time periods is ln(number of employees). Similarly, ln(total assets) showed normal distribution for both groups of firms, but only two periods prior to the event of insolvency. As within this study multivariate linear discriminant analysis has been applied, the occurrence of non-normal data could be a problem for model building, due to the risk that classification accuracy can be affected (Hopwood, McKeown & Mutchler, 1988; Klecka, 1989; Subhash, 1996; Keasey & Watson, 1991). This is not an extreme problem however, when departures from normality are only at a low level (Hopwood, McKewon & Mutchler, 1988; Silva, Stam & Neter, 2002; Feldesman, 2002). For some constellations of probability distribution, a departure can also be beneficial for improved discrimination between both groups, so that better classification accuracies can be achieved in comparison to logistic regression (Pohar, Blas & Turk 2004). Table 4: Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for normality of data Values in bold denote normally distributed data at 5 percent significance level 2003 2004 [two years prior to bankruptcy] [two years prior to bankruptcy] Ratio Class Statistic Sign. Skewness Statistic Sign. Skewness Total Equity/ 0 .361 .000 -3.344 .263 .003 -1.724 Total Assets 1 .253 .000 -4.526 .123 .000 -0.672 Total Debt/ 0 .361 .000 3.344 .263 .003 1.724 Total Assets 1 .253 .000 4.527 .123 .000 0.672 Sales/Total 0 .201 .065 1.963 .252 .005 2.010 Assets 1 .120 .000 1.834 .142 .000 1.884 ln(Sales/Total 0 .209 .046 -2.486 .142 .200 -0.571 Assets) 1 .113 .000 -1.654 .116 .000 -1.153 ln(Sales) 0 .201 .067 -1.587 .182 .138 0.275 1 .072 .030 0.579 .093 .001 0.755 ln(Number of 0 .135 .200 -0.969 .119 .200 -0.294 Employees) 1 .060 .200 0.199 .056 .200 0.075 2003 2004 [two years prior [two years prior to bankruptcy] to bankruptcy] Ratio Class Statistic Sign. Skewness Statistic Sign. Skewness ln(Sales/ 0 .201 .067 -1.587 .182 .138 0.275 Number of Employees) 1 .072 .030 0.579 .093 .001 0.755 ln(Staff Costs/ 0 .137 .200 0.105 .131 .200 -1.156 Number of Employees) 1 .128 .000 1.373 .101 .000 -0.652 Staff Costs/Sales 0 .519 .000 4.121 .420 .000 3.077 1 .309 .000 8.385 .234 .000 6.871 Sales/Staff Costs 0 .277 .001 2.441 .370 .000 3.752 1 .270 .000 5.465 .368 .000 6.974 EBITDA/Staff 0 .365 .000 -3.745 .212 .040 -1.635 Costs 1 .234 .000 4.662 .368 .000 6.120 EBIT/Staff 0 .394 .000 -3.834 .249 .006 -1.869 Costs 1 .313 .000 -5.735 .364 .000 6.536 EBIT/Sales 0 .536 .000 -4.123 .434 .000 -3.350 1 .478 .000 -12.954 .280 .000 -4.890 EBIT/Total 0 .268 .002 -2.275 .273 .002 -1.929 Assets 1 .370 .000 -11.711 .174 .000 -0.320 ln(Total Assets) 0 .173 .185 -0.271 .172 .196 -0.690 1 .067 .060 0.155 .076 .017 0.657 The problem of non-normal data appeared in several studies (Hauschildt, Rößler & Gemünden, 1984; Pacey & Pham, 1990; Barniv & McDonald, 1992; Baetge, Beuter & Feidicker, 1992; Lennox, 1999a; Chi & Tang, 2006; Yim & Mitchell, 2007; Samad, Yusof & Shaha-rudin, 2009), where this aspect was handled differently. Additionally, the approach of logistic regression should be more sound, as it does not demand normally distributed data, but several studies showed that this method is not generally able to deliver superior classification results when compared to multivariate linear discriminant analysis (Gentry, Newbold & Whit-ford, 1985; Gombola, Haskins, Ketz & Williams, 1987; Barniv & Raveh, 1989; Pacey & Pham, 1990; Barniv & McDonald, 1992; Neophytou & Mar Molinero, 2004; Kim & Gu, 2006). The aim of this study is not to develop a forecasting model. This study aims to test the potential prediction power of employee-related ratios in order to differentiate between bankrupt and non-bankrupt firms. Despite the non-normality of data being a given, multivariate linear discriminant analysis can nevertheless be used for such an attempt (Feldesman, 2002; Neophytou & Mar Molinero, 2005; Kim & Gu, 2006). Therefore, further progress was conducted without outlier deletion techniques or attempts concerning the normalization of data. Nevertheless, it must be kept in mind that this theoretical pre-condition is generally violated and that this may be attributable to weaker model quality and classification results. This aspect is also discussed within the section covering the limitations of the study. 7.3 Tests for differences in means and variances A test for differences in means and in variances at 5 percent level can be applied to detect the variables with the highest potential as discriminators between the two groups of companies. Mainly due to non-normally distributed data additionally, a U-test was considered (Ho, 2006, p. 357 and 368). In this case it is the more suitable method for decision and evaluation, and the results from the two aforementioned methods are displayed for informational purposes. The results are presented in the Tables 5 and 6. Many more variables can be found for the period one year prior to bankruptcy, which indicates that the signalling power increases as the event of bankruptcy approaches. This is in congruence with the generally accepted view that early detection is much more difficult (i.e. the signals are much weaker or less forthcoming) when the distance in time to the event of bankruptcy increases (Altman, 1968; Blum, 1974; Altman, Haldeman & Narayanan, 1977; Dambolena & Khoury, 1980; Mensah, 1984; Barniv & McDonald, 1992; Lennox 1999a; Laitinen & Laitinen, 2000; Chi & Tang, 2006; Korol & Korodi, 2011). According to the results, certain variables remain, which could act as potential predictors for the models. Table 5: Parametric and non-parametric test for differences two years prior to bankruptcy Values in bold denote statistically significant differences at the 5 percent level 2003 [two years prior to bankruptcy] t-test Levene-test U-Test Variables T Sign. F Sign. U Sign. Equity/Total Assets -1.646 0.102 0.118 0.731 914.000 0.013 Total Debt/Total Assets 1.644 0.102 0.119 0.730 914.000 0.013 Sales/Total Assets 1.664 0.098 5.483 0.020 1252.000 0.364 ln(Sales/Total Assets) 0.261 0.794 1.377 0.242 1252.000 0.364 ln(Sales) -2.654 0.009 0.031 0.860 955.000 0.021 ln(Number of Employees) -0.974 0.331 2.806 0.096 1237.500 0.329 ln(Sales/Number of Employees) -2.654 0.009 0.031 0.860 955.000 0.021 ln(Staff Costs/ Number of Employees) -1.817 0.071 0.136 0.713 916.000 0.013 Staff Costs/Sales 3.139 0.002 41.265 0.000 1176.000 0.206 Sales/Staff Costs -1.050 0.295 1.877 0.172 1176.000 0.206 EBITDA/Staff Costs -1.677 0.095 0.161 0.689 1014.000 0.043 EBIT/Staff Costs -0.531 0.596 0.099 0.754 1132.000 0.141 EBIT/Sales -2.482 0.014 25.694 0.000 1086.000 0.092 EBIT/Total Assets -0.130 0.897 0.027 0.870 1200.000 0.250 ln(Total Assets) -3.010 0.003 1.869 0.173 720.000 0.001 All of the significant variables in 2003 based on U-test (the only exception is ln(staff costs/ number of employees) are also statistically significant at the 5 percent level in 2004. This indicates that these ratios are able to provide much earlier warning signals concerning the economic situation of the firm. In 2004, four additional ratios showed discriminatory power to make a distinction between the two types of firms (ln(number of employees), EBIT/staff costs, EBIT/sales and EBIT/total assets). All other ratios are insignificant and can therefore be excluded from further analysis. A more profound insight can be achieved using correlation and factor analysis. Table 6: Parametric and non-parametric test for differences one year prior to bankruptcy Values in bold denote statistically significant differences at the 5 percent level 2004 [one year prior to bankruptcy] t-test Levene-test U-Test Variables T Sign. F Sign. U Sign. Equity/Total Assets -8.194 0.000 119.091 0.000 574.000 0.000 Total Debt/Total Assets 8.194 0.000 119.091 0.000 574.000 0.000 Sales/Total Assets 0.353 0.724 1.818 0.179 1377.000 0.749 ln(Sales/Total Assets) -0.334 0.739 0.827 0.364 1377.000 0.749 ln(Sales) -2.784 0.006 0.639 0.425 853.000 0.005 ln(Number of Employees) -2.748 0.007 0.430 0.513 870.500 0.007 ln(Sales/Number of Employees) -2.784 0.006 0.639 0.425 853.000 0.005 ln(Staff Costs/ Number of -1.340 0.182 0.067 0.796 1202.000 0.253 Employees) Staff Costs/Sales 3.065 0.003 23.353 0.000 1051.000 0.064 Sales/Staff Costs -0.918 0.360 1.858 0.175 1051.000 0.064 EBITDA/Staff Costs -1.693 0.092 0.375 0.541 846.000 0.005 EBIT/Staff Costs -1.781 0.077 0.097 0.756 770.000 0.002 EBIT/Sales -4.795 0.000 77.533 0.000 846.000 0.005 EBIT/Total Assets -6.968 0.000 110.293 0.000 734.000 0.001 ln(Total Assets) -4.085 0.000 0.667 0.415 699.000 0.000 7.4 Correlation analysis and factor analysis The complete results of correlation analysis based on Pearson for the two years prior to the event of bankruptcy can be found in the appendix of this work. Within Tables 7 and 8, the correlations for the most relevant variables based on U-test are reported. The general results show some highly positive and significant correlations between variables, which imposes multicollinearity. This occurrence can affect the discrimination power of models when such variables are included within prediction models (Hosmer & Lemeshow, 2000; Thomas, Edelman & Crook, 2002; Silva, Stam & Neter, 2002; Wooldridge, 2006; Asteriou & Hall, 2007). Multicollinearity can therefore be assumed for the following constellations: • Ln(sales) and ln(sales/number of employees) for both years • Total equity/total assets and EBIT/total assets for 2004 • EBITDA/staff costs and EBIT/staff costs for 2004 This implies that not all of these variables should be used for model building, because information redundancy is taken as a given. Besides this, there are several negative correlations which are potentially interesting for model building. Table 7: Correlation analysis for two years prior to bankruptcy Values in bold denote statistically significant correlations at the 1 percent level o/T y/t ui q E oT lat toT a S u uN a S y lo lp pm E s ore U 1 ö t ee r p p ■2 u-> ^ ^ s t t ae a ^ s o n ro (U £ о £ e 0 g О CN Es о r t t ^ д 5 ^ kg ад УЗ 43 ^ 1 'S ^ ад £ * Ш 1 g s се iS .О ю M o О baT (s}3ssviB}ox)u] siassypjiox/nga sajBS/Iiaa s}so3 jre/uaa s}so3 jjBis/vanaa SJS03 J}B}S/S3IBS S3]BS/S}S03 JJB1S (saaXojdrna jo jaqrnnN/sjso3 JJU}S)UI saaXojdrna jo jaqmnf^/sajBgJu] (saaXojdrna jo jaqumf^u] (sapjs)ui (SJ3SSy/]BJOXS3]BS)U] siassypjiox/saiBS spssyjBjoj/jmba -О 0) tu Q Vj V. < 3 '•3 о ir 15 о H H H £< J= (s}3ssvp3}ox)u] spssypnox/naH sai^s/iiaa sjsco j^s/uaa s}so3 jre/vauaa SJS03 iJU}S/S3IBS S3]BS/S}S03 JJBÌS (saaXojdrng jo jaqimiN/s}sco JpiS)uI saatojdrng jo jaqmnf^/sajBgJu] (saaXojdrng jo jaqumf^u] (S3IBS)UI (s}3ssv/IB}oxsap!s)ui spssypnox/sajus sj3ssy]Bjox/}qaQ]i2}ox spssyjBjcx/jmbg о CJ сл < M ^ m о m и о и Ча я M я M < rt я M < rt (s}3ssvp3}ox)ui sjassviBiox/naH sajBS/Iiaa sjsco jre/uaa s}so3 j^s/vauaa SJS03 iJU}S/S3IBS S3]BS/S}S03 JJBÌS (saaXojdrng jo jaqimiN/s}sco JFÌS)UI saaXojdrng jo jaqmnf^/sajBgJu] (saaXojdrng jo jaqumf^u] (S3IBS)UI (s}3ssv/IB}oxsap!s)ui spssypnox/sajus sjassviBìox/ìqaai^ìox spssy^cq/jmbg < Ti £ 3 U О & H и Q < < ■ä ss ss Š & J3 J3 J3 w (s}3ssvp3}ox)ui spssypnox/naH sajBs/uaa sjsco jre/uaa s}so3 jre/vauaa SJS03 iJU}S/S3IBS S3IBS/SÌS0D (saaXojdrng jo jaqimiN/s}sco JpiS)uI saatojdrng jo jaqmnf^/sajBgJu] (saaXojdrng jo jaqmnf^)ui (S3IBS)UI (s}3ssv/IB}oxsap!s)ui spssypnox/sajus sjassvjBìox/ìqaaiBìox spssyjBjcx/jmbg « ^ Л о о CJ m J5 Z ы о U о CJ о CJ < О H Я M О и Я M Я M < ■ti Я M REFERENCES Altman, E. I., Sabato, G. & Wilson, N. (2010). The value of non-financial information in small and medium-sized enterprise risk management. The Journal of Credit Risk, 6(2), 1-33. Altman, E. I. & Saunders, A. (1998). Credit risk measurement: Development over the last 20 years. Journal of Banking & Finance, 21, 1721-1742. Altman, E. I., Haldeman, R. G. & Narayanan, P. (1977). ZETATM analysis: A new model to identify bankruptcy risk of corporations. Journal of Banking and Finance, 1, 29-54. Altman, E. I. (1968). Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy. The Journal of Finance, 23(4), 589-609. Anandarajan, M., Lee, P. & Anandarajan, A. (2001). Bankruptcy prediction of financially stressed firms: An examination of the predictive accuracy of artificial neural networks. International Journal of Intelligent Systems in Accounting, Finance & Management, 10, 69-81. Anderson, R. (2007). The credit scoring toolkit: Theory and practice for retail credit risk management and decision automation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Asteriou, D. & Hall, S. G. (2007). Applied econometrics: A modern approach. New York: Palgrave. Baetge, J., Beuter, H. & Feidicker, M. (1992). Kreditwürdigkeitsprüfung mit Diskriminanzanalyse. Die Wirtschaftsprüfung, 24, 749-761. Bahiraie, A., Akma bt Ibrahim, N. & Azhar, A. K. M. (2009). On the predictability of risk box approach by genetic programming method for bankruptcy prediction. American Journal of Applied Sciences, 6(9), 1748-1757. Barniv, R. & McDonald, J. B. (1992). Identifying financial distress in the insurance industry: A synthesis of methodological and empirical issues. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 59(4), 543-574. Barniv, R. & Raveh, A. (1989). Identifying financial distress: A new nonparametric approach. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 16(3), 361-383. Bartual, C., Garcia, F., Gimenez, V. & Romero-Civera, A. (2012). Credit risk analysis: Reflection on the use of the logit model. Journal of Applied Finance & Banking, 2(6), 1-13. Beaver, W. H. (1966). Financial ratios as predictors of failure. Empirical Research in Accounting: Selected Studies, 4, 71-111. Begley, J., Ming, J. & Watts, S. (1996). Bankruptcy classification errors in the 1980s: An empirical analysis of Altman's and Ohlson's models. Review of Accounting Studies, 1, 267-284. Bhattacharjee, A., Higson, C., Holly, S. & Kattuman, P. (2009). Macroeconomic instability and business exit: Determinants of failures and acquisitions of UK firms. Economica, 76, 108-131 Blum, M. (1974). Failing company discriminant analysis. Journal of Accounting Research, 12(1), 1-25. Brabazon, A. & Keenan, P. B. (2004). A hybrid genetic model for the prediction of corporate failure. Computational Management Science, 1, 293-310. Bruse, H. (1978). Die Prognosefähigkeit von Kennzahlen bei verschiedenen Maßen für das Unternehmenswachstum. Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft, 48, 138-152. Bryant, S. M. (1997). A case-based reasoning approach to bankruptcy prediction modeling. Intelligent Systems in Accounting, Finance and Management, 6, 195-214. Burns, R. B. & Burns, R. A. (2008). Business research methods and statistics using SPSAS. London: Sage. Casey, C. & Bartczak, N. (1985). Using operating cash flow data to predict financial distress: Some extensions. Journal of Accounting Research, 23(1), 384-401. Castanias, R. (1983). Bankruptcy risk and optimal capital structure. The Journal of Finance, 38(5), 1617-1635. Chalos, P. (1985). Financial distress: A comparative study of individual, model, and committee assessments. Journal of Accounting Research, 23(2), 527-543. Chancharat, N., Tian, G., Davy, P., McCrae, M. & Lodh, S. (2010). Multiple states of financially distressed companies: Tests using a competing risk-model. Australasian Accounting Business and Finance Journal, 4(4), 27-44. Chatterjee, S. & Srinivasan, V. (1992). Graphical analysis and financial classification: A case study. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13, 527-537. Chaudhuri, A. (2013). Bankruptcy prediction using Bayesian, hazard, mixed logit and rough Bayesian models: A comparative analysis. Computer and Information Science, 6(2), 103-125. Chava, S. & Jarrow, R. A. (2004). Bankruptcy prediction with industry effects. Review of Finance, 8, 537-569. Chen, J., Marshall, B. R. Zhang, J., & Ganesh, S. (2006). Financial distress prediction in China. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 9(2), 317-336. Chi, L.-C. & Tang, T.-C. (2006). Bankruptcy prediction: Application of logit analysis in export credit risks. Australian Journal of Management, 31(1), 17-27. Coats, P. K. & Fant, F. L. (1993). Recognizing financial distress patterns using a neural network tool. Financial Management, 22, 142-155. Dambolena, I. G. & Khoury, S. J. (1980). Ratio stability and corporate failure. The Journal of Finance, 35(4), 1017-1026. Dawley, D. D., Hoffman, J. J. & Brockman, E. N. (2003). Do size and diversification type matter? An examination of post-bankruptcy outcomes. Journal of Managerial Issues, 15(4), 413-439. Dietrich, J., Arcelus, F. J. & Srinivasan, G. (2005). Predicting financial failure: Some evidence from new Brunswick agricultural co-ops. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 76(2), 179-194. Doumpos, M. & Zopounidis, C. (1998). A multicriteria discrimination method for the prediction of financial distress: The case of Greece. Multinational Finance Journal, 3(2), 71-101. Exler, M. W. & Situm, M (2013). Früherkennung von Unternehmenskrisen: Systematische Einteilung von Krisenfrüherkennungsindikatoren zu den unterschiedlichen Krisenphasen eines Unternehmens. Krisen-, Sani-erungs- und Insolvenzberatung, 9(4), 161-166. Fawcett, T. (2006). An introduction to ROC analysis. Pattern Recognition Letters, 27, 861-874. Feldesman, M. R. (2002). Classification trees as an alternative to linear discriminant analysis. American Journal of Physical Anthropology, 119, 257-275. Fitzpatrick, J. & Ogden, J. P. (2011). The detection and dynamics of financial distress. International Review of Finance, 11(1), 87-121. Foster, B. P., Ward, T. J. & Woodroof, J. (1998). An analysis of the usefulness of debt defaults and going concern opinions in bankruptcy risk assessment. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 13(3), 351-371. Frydman, H., Altman, E. I. & Kao, D.-L. (1985). Introducing recursive partitioning for financial classification: The case of financial distress. The Journal of Finance, 40(1), 269-291. Gebhardt, G. (1980). Insolvenzfrüherkennung aus aktienrechtlichen Jahresabschlüssen. Wiesbaden: Gabler. Gilbert, L. R., Menon, K. & Schwartz, K. B. (1990). Predicting bankruptcy for firms in financial distress. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 17(1), 161-171. Gombola, M. J., Haskins, M. E., Ketz, E. J. & Williams, D. D. (1987). Cash flow in bankruptcy prediction. Financial Management, 16, 55-65. Grunert, J., Norden, L. & Weber, M. (2005). The role of non-financial factors in internal credit ratings. Journal of Banking & Finance, 29, 509-531. Gudmundsson, S. V. (2002). Airline distress prediction using non-financial indicators. Journal of Air Transportation, 7(2), 3-24. Hauschildt, J., Rösler, J. & Gemünden, H. G. (1984). Der Cash Flow - Ein Krisensignalwert? Die Betriebswirtschaft, 44(3), 353-370. Ho, R. (2006), Handbook of univariate and multivariate data analysis and interpretation with SPSS. Boca Raton: Chapman & Hall. Hosmer, D. W. & Lemeshow, S. (2000). Applied logistic regression (2nd ed.). Massachusetts: John Wiley.. Hol, S. (2007). The influence of the business cycle on bankruptcy probability. International Transactions in Operational Research, 14, 75-90. Hopwood, W., McKeown, J. & Mutchler, J. (1988). The sensitivity of financial distress prediction models to departures from normality. Contemporary Accounting Research, 5(1), 284-298. Keasey, K. & Watson, R. (1991). Financial distress prediction models: A review of their usefulness. British Journal of Management, 2, 89 - 102. Klecka, W. R. (1980). Discriminant analysis. Newbury Park: Sage. Iazzolino, G., Migliano, G. & Gregorace, E. (2013). Evaluating intellectual capital for supporting credit risk assessment: An empirical study. Investment Management and Financial Innovations, 10(2), 44-54. Kim, H. & Gu, Z. (2006). Predicting restaurant bankruptcy: A logit model in comparison with a discriminant model. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research, 30(4), 474-493. Korol, T. & Korodi, A. (2011). An evaluation of effectiveness of fuzzy logic model in predicting the business bankruptcy. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting, 3, 92-107. Laitinen, E. K. & Laitinen, T. (2000). Bankruptcy prediction: Application of the Taylor's expansion in logistic regression. International Review of Financial Analysis, 9, 327-349. Lennox, C. (1999a). Identifying failing companies: A re-evaluation of the logit, probit and DA approaches. Journal of Economics and Business, 51, 347-364. Lennox, C. S. (1999b). The accuracy and incremental information content of audit reports in predicting bankruptcy. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 26(5/6), 757-778. Li, H. & Sun, J. (2011). Empirical research of hybridizing principal component analysis with multivariate discriminant analysis and logistic regression for business failure prediction. Expert Systems with Applications, 38, 6244-6253. Lin, R.-H., Wang, Y.-T., Wu, C.-H. & Chuang, C.-L. (2009). Developing business failure prediction model via RST, GRA and CBR. Expert Systems with Applications, 36, 1593-1600. Madrid-Guijarro, A., Garcia-Pèrez-de-Lema, D. & van Auken, H. (2011). An analysis of non-financial factors associated with financial distress. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 23(3/4), 159-186. Marchesini, R., Perdue, G. & Bryan V. (2004). Applying bankruptcy prediction models to distressed high yield bond issues. The Journal of Fixed Income, 13(4), 50-56. McKee, T. E. (2007). Altman's 1968 bankruptcy prediction model revisited via genetic programming: New wine from an old bottle or a better fermentation process? Journal of Emerging Technologies in Accounting, 4, 87-101. McKee, T. E. (1995). Predicting bankruptcy via induction. Journal of Information Technology, 10, 26-36. Mensah, Y. M. (1984). An examination of the stationarity of multivariate bankruptcy prediction models: A methodological study. Journal of Accounting Research, 22(1), 380-395. Metz, C. E. (1978). Basic principles of ROC analysis. Seminars in Nuclear Medicine, 8(4), 283-298. Min, J. J. & Lee, Y.-C. (2005). Bankruptcy prediction using support vector machine with optimal choice of kernel function parameter. Expert Systems with Applications, 28, 603-614. Muller, G. H., Steyn-Bruwer, B. W. & Hamman, W. D. (2009). Predicting financial distress of companies listed on JSE - A comparison of techniques. South African Journal of Business & Management, 40(1), 21-32. Nam, C. W., Kim, T. S., Park, N. J. & Lee, H. K. (2008). Bankruptcy prediction using a discrete-time duration model incorporating temporal macroeconomic dependencies. Journal of Forecasting, 27, 493-506. Neophytou, E. & Mar Molinero, C. (2004). Predicting corporate failure in the UK: A multidimensional scaling approach. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 31(5/6), 677-710. Neves, J. C. & Vieira, A. (2006). Improving bankruptcy prediction with hidden layer learning vector quantization. European Accounting Review, 15(2), 253-271. Ohlson, J. A. (1980). Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy. Journal of Accounting Research, 18(1), 109-131. Ooghe, H. & Spaenjers, C. (2010). A note on performance measures for business failure prediction models. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 10(1), 21-32. Pacey, J. W. & Pham, T. M. (1990). The predictiveness of bankruptcy models: Methodological problems and evidence. Australian Journal of Management, 15(2), 315-337. Paradi, J. C., Asmild, M. & Simak, P. C. (2004). Using DEA and worst practice DEA in credit risk evaluation. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 21, 153-165 Pervan, I. & Kuvek, T. (2013). The relative importance of financial ratios and nonfinancial variables in predicting of insolvency. Croatian Operational Research Review, 4, 187-198. Pervan, M. & Visic, J. (2012). Influence of firm size on its business success. Croatian Operational Research Review, 3, 213-223. Platt, H. D., Platt, M. B. & Pedersen. J. G. (1994). Bankruptcy discrimination with real variables. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 21(4), 491-510. Pohar, M., Blas, M. & Turk, S. (2004). Comparison of logistic regression and linear discriminant analysis: A simulation study. Metdološki Zvezki, 1(1), 143-161. Pompe, P. P. & Bilderbeek, J. (2005). Bankruptcy prediction: The influence of the year prior to failure selected for model building and the effects in a period of economic decline. Intelligent Systems in Accounting, Finance and Management, 13, 95-112. Pretorius, M. (2008). Critical variables of business failure: A review and classification framework. South African Journal of Economics and Business, 11(4), 408-430. Samad, F., Yusof, M. A. M. & Shaharudin, R. S. (2009). Financial distress risk and stock returns: Evidence form the Malaysian stock market. Journal of International Finance and Economics, 9(2), 19-38. Shah, J. R. & Murtaza, M. B. (2000). A neural network based clustering procedure for bankruptcy prediction. American Business Review, 18(2), 80-86. Shin, K-S., Lee, T. S. & Kim, H.-j. (2005). An application of support vector machines in bankruptcy prediction model. Expert Systems with Applications, 28, 127 - 135. Silva, D. A. P., Stam, A. & Neter, J. (2002). The effects of misclassification costs and skewed distributions in two-group classification, Communications in Statistics - Simulation and Computation, 31(3), 401-423. Situm, M. (2014). The age and the size of the firm as relevant predictors for bankruptcy. Journal of Applied Economics and Business, 2 (1), 5 - 30. Subhash, S. (1996). Applied multivariate techniques. New York: John Wiley. Sudarsanam, S. & Lai, J. (2001). Corporate financial distress and turnaround strategies: An empirical analysis. British Journal of Management, 12, 183-199. Theodossiou, P., Kahya, E., Saidi, R. & Philippatos, G. (1996). Financial distress and corporate acquisitions: Further empirical evidence. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 23(5), 699-719. Thomas, L. C., Edelman, D. B. & Crook, J. N. (2002). Credit scoring and its applications. Philadelphia: Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics. Thornhill, S. & Amit, R. (2003). Learning about failure: Bankruptcy, firm age, and the resource-based view. Organization Science, 14(5), 497-509. Wang, W. T. & Zhou, X. (2011). Could traditional financial indicators predict the default of small and medium-sized enterprises? International Proceedings on Economics and Finance Research, 4, 72-76. Wetter, E. & Wennberg, K. (2009). Improving business failure prediction for new firms: Benchmarking financial models with human and social capital. The Journal of Private Equity, 12(2), 30-37. Whitaker, R. B. (1999). The early stages of financial distress. Journal of Economics and Finance, 23(2), 123-133. Wilson, N., Chong, K. W. & Peel, M. J. (1995). Neural network simulation and the prediction of corporate outcomes: Some empirical findings. International Journal of Economics of Business, 2(1), 31-50. Wooldridge, J. M. (2006). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach (3rd ed.). Mason: Thomson. Yeh, C.-C., Chi, D.-J. & Hsu, M.-F. (2010). A hybrid approach of DEA, rough set and support vector machines for business failure prediction. Expert Systems with Applications, 37, 1535-1541. Yim, J. & Mitchell, H. (2007). Predicting financial distress in the Australian financial service industry. Australian Economic Papers, 46(4), 375-388. Zmijewski, M. E. (1984). Methodological issues related to the estimation of financial distress prediction models. Journal of Accounting Research, 22(Supp.), 59-82. SCIENCE-INDUSTRY COOPERATION IN SLOVENIA: DETERMINANTS OF SUCCESS MAJA BUČAR1 Received: 13 July 2014 MATIJA ROJEC 2 Accepted: 13 September 2014 ABSTRACT: Paper analyses barriers to science-industry cooperation in Slovenia through three detailed case studies. Each case tackles both sides, industry (firms) and science (university/ research institute). Case studies confirm our assumption that it is the lack of companies with in-house R&D activities which is the main structural deficit for more science-industry cooperation. Strengthening of firms' in-house R&D departments and staff, and clustering of firms around the most propulsive ones is the precondition for more science-industry cooperation. Successful science-industry cooperation can only be developed gradually, most often on the basis of previous personal contacts between main actors on both sides. Case studies reflect no impact of the intermediary institutions on science-industry cooperation. Keywords: science-industry cooperation, Slovenia, case studies JEL Classification: O32, O33, O38 1. INTRODUCTION Science-industry cooperation, i.e. cooperation between universities and government or public research institutes (public research organisations - PROs), on one side, and firms, on the other, has attracted considerable attention in the literature as well as in the policy discussions3. From firms' perspective, it is a part of a broader process of innovation cooperation as an increasingly prominent feature of firms' innovation activity. Conceptually - Narula (2003) within the industrial organisation network, Chesbrough (2006) within the Open Innovation Paradigm, Cohen and Levinthal (1989, 1990) and Mowery and Rosenberg (1989 - the key issue of innovation cooperation has to do with explanatory mechanisms related to firms' in-house R&D versus external sourcing of knowledge, innovation cooperation being one mode of external sourcing. The literature points to the complementarity of internal, in-house R&D and external knowledge sourcing, i.e. to the optimal integration of external knowledge into internal R&D of (Radnor, 1991; Veugelers and Cassiman, 1999; Criscuolo and Narula, 2008). 1 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Social Sciences, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: maja.bucar@fdv.uni-lj.si 2 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Social Sciences & Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: matija.rojec@gov.si 3 As found by Izsak, Markianidu and Radošević (2013:17) in the EU Report on Decade of innovation Policy, »during the course of 2000s, the "mantra" of innovation policies has been to foster industry science links with diverse efforts being made to gear research towards business...« Along these lines empirical research on the impact of innovation cooperation on firm's innovation capacity, as a rule, finds a strong positive relationship between innovation networking and innovation output (see, for instance Cohen and Levinthal, 1989, 1990; Mowery and Rosenberg, 1989; Veugelers, 1997; Veugelers and Cassiman, 1999; Belderbos et al., 2004a; Kremp and Mairesse, 2004; Arvanitis and Bolli, 2009 etc.). Empirical studies specifically dealing with science-industry cooperation say that for firms cooperation with PROs may be as useful, sometimes even more, than cooperation with other firms (Arvanitis and Bolli, 2009; Belderbos et al., 2004b; Guliani and Arza, 2009; Bercovitz and Feldman, 2007). Still, science-industry cooperation does not seem to be among the most frequent or the most important types of firms' innovation cooperation. In 2010, the share of Slovenian innovative firms engaged in innovation cooperation with universities was 49.1% and of those engaged in cooperation with government or public research institutes 31.9%.4 This qualifies science-industry cooperation as less frequent type of innovation cooperation (see table in Appendix 1), in spite of the fact that the promotion of industry- science cooperation has been high on the innovation policy agenda. The situation in EU27 is similar and even at a lower level. It also seems that firms on average treat science-industry cooperation as less important than innovation cooperation with other partners. Only 16% of Slovenian firms with innovation cooperation claim that cooperation with universities is the most valuable to them while the corresponding share for cooperation with government or public research institutes is even lower, i.e. 10.3%.5 The objective of this paper is to analyse science-industry cooperation in Slovenia, more precisely to look at the motivation behind cooperation, to identify problems and obstacles on one and the other side, as well as in innovation policy and institutional framework. Finally, we suggest what should be done at science, business and government level to intensify the science-industry cooperation with the ambition to achieve long-term growth based on innovation. In an environment of a small transition country, where in comparison to the bigger, more developed economies, limited R&D resources are available, it is imperative that cooperation of all existing scientific potential is stimulated. Of the countries that have joined EU in 2004-2007, Slovenia was the first transition country, which managed to join the group of innovation followers according to the IUS (EC, 2011). Also, according to World Economic Forum (WEF), only Slovenia is classified as a country in the innovation-driven stage of growth (WEF, 2007) of the 27 CEE/CIS countries ranked. Yet, the degree of cooperation between the public science sector and business R&D has been identified as one of the weaker elements of the country's innovation system by OECD (2011), ERAC (2010) as well as national evaluations (RISS, 2011) and thus a focus of several policy actions. The experience of Slovenia can therefore be of relevance to other smaller, research & innovation less intensive countries. Based on the relevant theoretical considerations and existing empirical evidence we will test the hypotheses that frequency and extent of science industry cooperation depends 4 This has been quite an increase from 2004-2006 CIS data, when the corresponding shares were 19.4% and 13.2% respectively, as well as from 2006-2008 CIS, when the shares were added. 5 For 20.5% of firms performing innovation cooperation, the most valuable is innovation cooperation with suppliers, for 18.6% with clients or customers, for 9.6% with other firms within the group and for 9.2% with the competitors. on: (i) the extent and nature of firms' in-house R&D and innovation activity, which also determine their absorption capacity, (ii) the existence of quality research and scientific productivity in PROs, critical mass of knowledge in specific areas of expertise, and on motivation of researchers, (iii) the development of a portfolio of intermediary institutions and their quality, and on (iv) the adequacy of national policy and institutional framework, supporting science industry cooperation. The analysis is based on the three detailed case studies of science industry cooperation6. Each case is approached from both sides, i.e. concepts, motivation, problems, barriers etc. in individual cases are analysed from the perspective of firms and of the university/ research institute. To the best of our knowledge this is the first such analysis for the transition countries of Central and Eastern European (CEE) countries and its conclusions may be of relevance for other small transition economies with a similar R&D potential. The interviews convey two main messages. The first is that it is the lack of companies with inhouse R&D activities which is the main structural deficit for more intensive science-industry cooperation. Strengthening of firms' in-house R&D departments and staff, and clustering of firms around the most propulsive ones is the precondition and possibly most effective measure for more science-industry cooperation. The second is that there are no fast breakthroughs in science-industry cooperation; successful cooperation can only be developed gradually, from specific small initial tasks to a more comprehensive collaboration. Also, case studies reflect no impact of the intermediary institutions on science-industry cooperation. The paper is structured as follows. Introduction is followed by a short overview of theoretical considerations and empirical evidence on science industry cooperation in section two. Section three presents the cases, where each case first presents main features, motivation and development of innovation, then determinants and problems of cooperation. Section four concludes with suggestions of the measures for strengthening innovation capacity and science industry cooperation. 2. THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Among the most prominent theoretical concepts of science industry cooperation is the so called Triple Helix Model by Etzkowitz and Leydesdorff (1997), and Viale and Etz-kowitz (2010) which points to the new relationships between business, university and government, and claims that academia should be closely integrated with the industrial world (Eun et al., 2006). Yet we also have a different view of the New Economics of Science (Dasgupta and David, 1994) and some others (Mowery and Sampat, 2004; Lundvall, 2002) who are concerned by a too close integration of science into industry and opt for a proper division of labour between the two. The latter view is based on the recognition 6 Several other research projects have been implemented by the authors, where industry-science R&D cooperation has been analysed- from the perspective of public R&D organisations (Mali et al, 2004), analysis based on case studies of 22 export-oriented R&D intensive companies (Bučar, 2010), analysis of intermediary organisations and innovation policy measures (Jaklič et al, 2012), etc. The outcomes of these led to the approach applied in this paper: simultaneous analysis of three cases of R&D cooperation from the perspective of PRO as well as of the enterprise. that science and industry are two distinctively organized and functionally differentiated spheres (Dasgupta and David, 1994), and that norms of science and industry differ very much. In this paper, we take a more pragmatic perspective of context-specific perspective of science-industry relationship developed by Eun et al. (2006) in which the relationship depends on country specific economic conditions and where the basic determinants of relationship are internal resources of university, absorptive capacity of industrial firms and existence of intermediary institutions. 2.1. Science-industry cooperation: firms' view Existing studies identify one or more of the following benefits of science-industry collaboration for firms: (i) access to state-of-the art knowledge and information, (ii) developing new products/processes, (iii) maintaining relationship with university researchers, (iv) access to students as potential employees, (v) increased patenting (Lee, 2000; Venniker and Jongbloed, 2002; Belderbos et al., 2004a). For CEE countries, Radošević (2011:373) also cites that universities and research institutes provide access to equipment to test the raw materials and finished products' quality. List of factors that determine the motivation of firms for science industry cooperation is quite long, far the most often quoted being in-house R&D and absorption capacity, appro-priability conditions and the nature of firm's R&D and innovation activity. Firms' in-house R&D and their absorption capacity in general - denoted by own R&D, level of technology, human capital - is definitely the main determinant which increases firms' propensity for R&D cooperation with universities (Arvanitis and Bolli, 2009; Giuliani and Arza, 2009; Kodama, 2008; Bercovitz and Feldman, 2007). Nature of firm's in-house R&D and innovation activity is the next determinant of its cooperation with university. Firms that are more engaged in basic exploratory research, have higher knowledge base and introduce more advanced innovations tend to cooperate with universities (see Bercovitz and Feldman, 2007; Giuliani and Arza, 2009). For Bolli and Woerter (2011) firms' university cooperation corresponds to product innovation and hence quality competition, while cooperation with competitors lead to process innovations and therefore relates to price competition. A number of other firm- related factors are also claimed to have the impact on cooperation with universities, i.e. firm's size, firm's propensity to innovation cooperation as such and its openness to external environment in general, extent of public funding, industry specific characteristics, individual characteristics of the researchers involved, and institutional environment in which knowledge is produced and used (Arvanitis and Bolli, 2009; Cassiman and Veugelers, 2002; Veugelers and Cassiman, 2005). Extent of public funding or joint participation of universities and firms in national R&D projects have proved to be another factor in favour of more science industry cooperation (Arvanitis and Bolli, 2009; Jensen et al., 2010). 2.2. Science-industry cooperation: science's view Universities may benefit from collaboration with industry in several ways: (i) getting access to additional research funding, (ii) additional equipment and facilities, (iii) additional information and data, (iv) increased number of publications and innovations, (v) better insights into their own research and access to new research problems, (vi) channel for knowledge transfer, (vii) improved quality of teaching and providing students with insights in industry research, (viii) securing funds and improved job opportunities for their students (Lee, 2000; Venniker and Jongbloed, 2002). Quality of university research, motivation of academic researchers and intermediating mechanisms are the main determinants of science- industry cooperation on university side. Empirical evidence suggests a positive relationship between academics' research quality and commercialization of research activities (Perkman et al., 2011; Van Looy et al., 2011). Motivation of universities, i.e. university researchers for cooperation with industry is often hindered by the fact that science and industry are still two distinctively organized and functionally differentiated spheres, where norms and values differ very much. Lam (2011) claims that a diversity of motivations exists, where many university researchers cooperate for the reputational and intrinsic reasons with financial rewards playing a relatively small part. D'Este and Patel (2007) add that individual characteristics of researchers may be more important than characteristics of their departments or universities. 2.3. Science-industry cooperation: the role of intermediary institutions In analysing barriers to university-industry collaboration, Bruneel et al. (2010) distinguish orientation-related differences from transaction-related barriers (conflicts over intellectual property, dealing with university administration). They find that prior experience of collaborative research lowers orientation related barriers, that greater levels of trust reduce both types of barriers, and that breadth of interaction diminishes orientation-related but increases transaction-related barriers. Inter-organizational trust is claimed to be one of the strongest mechanisms for lowering the barriers to interaction between universities and industry. 'Building trust between academics and industrial practitioners requires long-term investment in interactions, based on mutual understanding about different incentive systems and goals. It also necessitates a focus on face-to-face contacts between industry and academia, initiated through personal referrals and sustained by repeated interactions' (Bruneel et al., 2006: 867). Similarly, Balconi and Laboranti (2006) find that university industry cooperation is based on teams of researchers on both sides; strong connections are associated with high scientific performance, cognitive proximity and personal relationships. A number of other authors point to the importance of intermediary institutions between university and industry. Universities with established policies and procedures for the management of technology transfer (technology transfer offices, science parks) perform better as far as science industry cooperation is concerned (Caldera and Debande, 2010). Staff employed by the intermediaries is also important. Conti and Gaule (2011) claim that one of the reasons why US outperform Europe in university technology licensing is that US technology transfer officers employ more staff with experience in industry. 3. MAIN FEATURES OF THE ANALYSED CASE STUDIES OF SCIENCE INDUSTRY COOPERATION The above overview puts forward the following propositions to be tested by the case studies. Frequency and extent of science industry cooperation depends on: (i) firms, i.e. on the extent and nature of firms' in-house R&D and innovation activity, which also determine their absorption capacity, (ii) universities7, i.e. existence of quality research and scientific productivity in PROs, on critical mass of knowledge in specific areas of expertise, and on motivation of researchers, (iii) intermediaries, i.e. on development of a portfolio of intermediary institutions (such as technology transfer offices, technology parks and centres, incubators and development agencies) and their quality, and on (iv) adequacy of national policy and institutional framework, supporting science industry cooperation. We analyse three cases of science-industry cooperation, one in chemical, one in pharmaceutical and one in food-processing industry. Each case can be characterised by a different level of research intensity of the firm as well as the size of firm. On the PRO side, we have both, a public research institute as well as university departments. In each case, partners from both sides have been interviewed, based on a semi-structured questionnaire covering six main topics: a/ Main features of the cooperation project: (i) motivation, (ii) objectives, (iii) development of cooperation, (iv) realisation of expectations; b/ Conditions for science-industry cooperation: (i) relevance of existing conditions for cooperation in the particular case, (ii) criteria in seeking cooperation partners, (iii) main strengths, weaknesses and difficulties of cooperation, (iv) do innovation system characteristics support science industry cooperation or not, (v) what is the explanation for the current state of science-industry cooperation; c/ Guiding principles of science-industry cooperation: (i) who should set the targets of cooperation, (ii) the most important criteria for the success of cooperation, (iii) how should the success be assessed; d/ What has been the most important knowledge in the particular case of cooperation: (i) which type of knowledge: tacit or codified - is more important for the particular case, (ii) how important are different ways of knowledge creation; do partners have different views on that; e/ Measures for improving innovation capacities in a particular sector: (i) areas in a particular sector where the innovation capacity is assessed as weak and the reasons for this, (ii) what measures should/could be introduced in the particular company/ PRO to improve innovation capacity; f/ What must science and industry change/do in order to improve cooperation: (i) which strategies should be implemented at the level of national innovation system to improve the exchange between science and industry, (ii) good and bad examples of cooperation and the reasons behind them (iii) how supportive was the innovation infrastructure in facilitating cooperation? 7 The case studies include also cooperation with public research institutes, so we apply the term public research organisations- PROs throughout the text. The interviews were carried out in 2009 and 2010. For the list of interviewees and partner institutions see Appendix 2. 3.1. Case 1: Cooperation in the field of structural determinations and texture analysis of pharmaceutical products 3.1.1. Main features, motivation and development of cooperation Case 1 analyses cooperation between the Laboratory for Inorganic Chemistry and Technology of the National Institute of Chemistry Slovenia (referred in the text as the Laboratory) and Krka, a generic producer of pharmaceuticals, one of the largest companies in Slovenia with EUR 1,010 million of sales, EUR 171 million of net profit, 8,569 employees and 9.0% share of R&D expenditures in sales8. Chemical and especially pharmaceutical sectors are among the most R&D and innovation intensive sectors in Slovenia. For the pharmaceutical sector, permanent R&D and innovation is a sine qua non of existence. The same is true for chemistry and pharmaceuticals as a science. National Institute of Chemistry is the second largest research institution in Slovenia with 269 researchers, being among the most prominent in Slovenia in terms of publications and citations. Krka has a big R&D department, clearly set R&D objectives and invests significant amount in R&D in pharmaceuticals. On the other hand, pharmaceuticals are not among the Laboratory's basic activities. This determines the nature of cooperation, which is focused on very specific tasks, i.e. the use of Laboratory's Nuclear Magnetic Resonance (NMR) in analysing structural determinations and texture analysis of pharmaceutical products. This is necessary to assess whether Krka's generic medicines fulfil the patenting requirements. According to Krka's Director of Research, the Laboratory is capable of providing Krka with specific analytical work, which is closely supervised by Krka's internal research team. Krka assesses Laboratory's cooperation as highly beneficial. The Laboratory possesses equipment for specific testing purpose not available in Krka, excellent knowledge of a specific analytical technique and has specific knowledge/ skills, which are insufficiently available in Krka. Basic principle of cooperation is team work of Krka's and Laboratory's staff; this leads to significant level of cross-fertilisation of knowledge. The nature of work dictates very close cooperation on a daily basis with continuous monitoring of progress and active participation of research teams. Officially the cooperation is regulated through five-year framework contract between the Laboratory (and not the National Institute of Chemistry) and Krka, which gets annexed with specific annual programme of cooperation. Both Krka and Laboratory have comprehensive science-industry cooperation with other partners as well. Krka has a well-developed cooperation with various universities and R&D institutes in Slovenia and abroad. High R&D intensity of pharmaceuticals and the fact that R&D contents need to be well protected to avoid leakage of sensitive information determine company's cooperation with science. The nature of Krka's activity calls for a systematic development of all phases of the research process: (i) from the basic research, which is mainly done 8 Data for 2010, http://www.krka.si/media/prk/dokumenti/5200_krka_annual_report_2010_slo_200611.pdf internally due to highly specific knowledge required, (ii) to several testing phases, which are carried out internally and/or in close cooperation with specialised scientific institutions, and (iii) to monitoring of the quality, where again very specific external knowledge is being sought. The most important criteria in Krka's search and selection of partners from PROs are the type and quality of service/ specific knowledge, which can be provided. Krka's long experience in cooperation with PROs in Slovenia puts it in a position of a well-informed partner, who knows where the specific capacities and expertise is and how they can be best employed. Krka's systematic support of certain research areas has long-term effect in joint research projects development. In cases where the type of knowledge needed cannot be provided in Slovenia, Krka has a wide network of R&D partners in different countries. In each case of R&D outsourcing, cooperation is started on a relatively small, well defined topic, which, if results being satisfactory, has later evolved in a more permanent and broader cooperation. Since cooperations are carefully entered into and develop only after satisfactory 'trial deals, Krka experiences high satisfaction in cooperation with PROs. This was also the case with the National Institute of Chemistry, where Krka has cooperation agreements with several laboratories. Still, the PRO's responsiveness is sometimes less than required due to the relatively small size of human resources in public R&D sector in the specific topics that Krka needs. 3.1.2. Determinants and problems of cooperation Krka's involvement in science-industry cooperation is decisively influenced by its own intensive R&D activity and by R&D nature of the sector in which cooperation with science is a must. Also, Krka needs to have a very active recruitment policy and uses several different ways to secure sufficient inflow of human resources: different scholarships, competitions for best research studies and diploma works at the universities as well as direct cooperation with professors and researchers. The basic precondition for cooperation on the science side is the underlying philosophy of the Laboratory that it is its duty as a PRO to cooperate with industry, which differs from the more common approach of Slovenian PROs who often set their R&D priorities without taking into account the needs of the industry. Consequently, Slovenian researchers in PROs are often not specialised enough, which results in difficulties to respond to the specific needs of the industry. Objectives setting and mutual understanding of partners. Krka's Director of Research is very well aware that industry and science have different objectives in cooperation. People from the science sector are pressed for the bibliometric results, while researchers in industry need to apply the research results in production as quickly as possible to secure competitive position. In its science-industry cooperation, Krka clearly is a dominant partner. The goals and the contents of cooperation contracts with PROs are set by Krka. For Krka, the ultimate aim of cooperation is that it contributes to the introduction of new and/ or improved products and processes. Krka expects its science partners to respond in reasonably short time, be flexible and have a high level of knowledge and expertise. Ability to participate in a team work in developing new knowledge and adjustability of the research- ers is crucial; this is often achieved best by continuous exchange of personnel or by close interaction of the key personnel from both partners working on a particular issue. In cooperation with industry, the Laboratory looks for establishment of joint R&D capacities, sharing of R&D costs, experiences for students and practical verification of theoretical findings. Of course, money is important as well: 20% of Laboratory's budget comes from cooperation with industry. Laboratory's experience is that the cooperation is based primarily on well-identified needs and objectives of firm, which is a starting point of any science-industry cooperation. Both Krka's Director of Research and Head of the Laboratory stress the importance of gradual building of cooperation. Most of Laboratory's cooperation with industry began rather informally/ spontaneously and has developed gradually. The leading role of Krka in the cooperation is reflected also in its attitude to the knowledge resulting from the cooperation. In pharmaceuticals, the codified knowledge is of crucial importance. Krka has built in specific clause in all its cooperation agreements to protect the knowledge derived from joint R&D work. Krka expects its partners to act accordingly. In the case of science partners' research papers, their publication is often delayed to account for the time of obtaining the patent and is always pre-checked by the company. 3.1.3. Relevance of innovation policy measures The cooperation in this case has developed with no support from the government, even though both partners apply to various programmes under R&D and innovation policy. Krka does not need outside intermediary institutions due to the strength of its in-house R&D unit who has, as already mentioned a good overview of the scientific capacities at PROs in the country. One of the key problems identified by both partners is the irregularity in government's announcements and funding of support measures like co-financing of joint R&D projects. For a firm, which strategically depends on research inputs, the stability, transparency and regularity of available support measures is a key determinant of their effectiveness. This is why the programme of financing Young Researchers9 has been assessed as one of the most beneficial also from the science- industry cooperation point of view. 3.2. Case 2: Cooperation in the field of improving animal meat quality, with the aim of producing meat with enriched nutritive fatty acids 3.2.1. Main features, motivation and development of cooperation Case 2 analyses cooperation between Department of Animal Science, Faculty of Agriculture of the University of Zagreb (Croatia) and Emona RCP - Nutrition Research and Development Department of Jata Emona, which employs 265 people and is involved in the production and distribution of feeds for all domestic animal species, including various 9 The scheme has financed postgraduate study and research training for young researchers and enabled people from firms to go into the science sector for a certain period of time for M.A. or Ph. D. A candidate had to work on a particular research project within a firm, but received mentorship support at the public R&D unit (for more see http://cordis.europa.eu/erawatch/index.cfm?fuseaction=search.resultList). sorts of mixtures and vitamin enriched feeds. Cooperation was initiated by Emona RCP. The project looks into different impact feeds may have on the quality of meat with particular aim of enriching the animal feeds to produce more Omega 3 fatty acids in the animal's meat. Within cooperation Emona RCP has been primarily involved in the research on appropriate mixtures of feeds, while the task of the Department has been to investigate the influence of different corn varieties in the diet of pigs on pork fatty acid composition. 3.2.2. Determinants and problems of cooperation The interviewees recognise the need for science-industry cooperation in food-processing industry and acknowledge that existing science-industry links in the sector are very weak. They identify a number of barriers to more science-industry cooperation within the industry and the science sectors, in their mutual perception and relationship. Industry sector barriers. In Slovenia, agriculture and food processing have traditionally been treated as low-tech, low value-added industries where R&D has a limited role to play. There is no tradition of science-industry cooperation in Slovenian food processing sector and no dedicated intermediaries. The main barriers to more R&D and innovation in Slovenian agriculture and food processing firms are: (i) small size of firms, (ii) lack of R&D and innovation activities, of awareness of the need for R&D and of its potential contribution, (iii) small number of in-house R&D units in firms; (iv) inadequate financial instruments for R&D in food processing. Lack of R&D units seriously limits the opportunities for science-industry cooperation. The interest in most firms lies with cost reduction applications and relatively routine improvements in the processes. Their "R&D" or development departments mostly perform routine procedures, like quality control and testing. Investing in knowledge is not seen as a factor of competitive strategy. Jata Emona is no exception in this regard. Even the existing knowledge or capability to produce new knowledge by its own research unit-Emona RCP is not yet seen as company's competitive advantage. Science sector barriers. On the science side, two distinctive factors inhibit science-industry cooperation. The first is that Slovenian food technology science is predominantly concentrated at the Biotechnical Faculty of the University of Ljubljana. The people there are overloaded with teaching and publishing, with little motivation to do research/ consulting work for industry. The second factor is the lack of opportunities for human resource flows from science to industry sector. Slovenia simply does not have sufficiently large food processing firms to offer attractive career to highly educated people who could form inhouse R&D base. Objectives setting and mutual understanding of partners. According to Emona RCP and the Department, objectives of cooperation are quite different for each partner. Science sector looks for good internationally published papers, participation at international symposia, some additional financing, maybe also some teaching material. The research team in a business R&D unit must always think of finding practical applicable solutions, and finally of the maximisation of economic returns. Therefore it is of crucial importance to establish mutual understanding and trust between partners. In the case of cooperation between Emona RCP and the Department mutual understanding seems to be adequately established. At the science side, the empirical results of the project were used by the PhD candidate to complete his dissertation. At the business sector side, the expertise developed during the empirical research helped to develop new products and increase competitiveness. According to Emona RCP, successful cooperation projects work in the following way: testing enables the partner(s) at the university to generate empirically based research, suitable for publication, on one hand, and brings a working solution to the industrial process, on the other. The key determinant of the success is the ability of business R&D unit to act as an intermediary between the PRO and the firm. Cooperation of Emona RCP with different PROs has developed through years, first on the personal basis (researcher to researcher) and then upgraded into institutional cooperation in specific projects. The messages of Emona RCP - Department cooperation are that: (i) productive cooperation does not develop quickly or easily. Good cooperation can only be found where the partnership has been developing over a longer period of time, where both sides have learned to understand each other; (ii) competent R&D unit in a firm, with a good understanding of the potential of theoretical advancements for practical purposes and a good knowledge of the complexity of production process and its economics is the main factor in establishing mutual understanding between science and industry; (iii) objectives and targets of science-industry cooperation should primarily be formulated and set by the industry side. Within this context partners must come to a clear understanding of each others' objectives. Objectives of each side need to be recognised and respected by the other side. Joint work should be designed in way that both sides meet their objectives. Only in such way both sides benefit. 3.2.3. Relevance of innovation policy measures The awareness of the existence of policy measures, which could support their cooperation, was particularly low in this case. Partly, this can be attributed to the fact that often innovation measures exclude agriculture and food processing industry as the recipient sector. On the other hand, the interviewees mentioned that they believe their cooperation is so specific that it would not fit under standard joint-research project classification. According to Emona RCP, no intermediary institution is focusing on promotion of cooperation in the food processing sector or has the adequate knowledge in the field to act as such. 3.3. Case 3: Cooperation in the field of development of melamine-based foam 3.3.1. Main features, motivation and development of cooperation Case 3 analyses cooperation between the Department of the Polymer Engineering, Organic Chemical Technology and Material at the Faculty of Chemistry and Chemical Technology, University of Ljubljana (referred in the text as the Department) and chemical company Melamin. The cooperation under current contract began in 2002. Melamin manufactures melamine film sheets for finishing chipboards, resins, adhesives, synthetic sizing agents, impregnated textile materials for use in the footwear industry, has EUR 34.3 million of turnover and 192 employees. Cooperation is concentrated on the development of melamine-based foam and is formalised in a long-term contract. Department at the University is involved in the basic research - collection of the relevant literature on the subject, analytical and laboratory phase of research - which is then used by Melamin's R&D Unit for the applied research. The cooperation includes human resource development aspect, i.e. Melamin's employees pursue their postgraduate studies at the Faculty of Chemistry and Chemical Technology, while young researchers from the Department can apply their theoretical research to empirical testing in Melamin for the purpose of their doctoral theses. The cooperation is characterised by its gradual evolve-ment around specifically agreed research topics. Melamin has a long lasting cooperation with the University of Ljubljana, but initially the agreement was more a formality than contextually embedded in Melanin's production programme and Melamin's management was rather indifferent to science-industry cooperation. In 2002, today's Head of Melamin's R&D Unit joined the company. He completed his doctoral studies within the Young Researchers Programme under the mentorship of the Head of the Department. He proposed the establishment of cooperation of Melamin with the Department and succeeded to change the attitude of Melamin's management. At approximately the same time, Melamin launched a new development concept, based on two basic premises. The first had been that all the products should be based on the same raw material to increase the amount of the raw materials purchased and consequently decrease per unit purchasing prices. The second premise had been to diversify end products and increase the value added. Here, the R&D Unit was expected to play the key role. The in- house R&D capability was insufficient to meet the new requests, therefore Melamin leaned on the cooperation with the Department. The crucial push was the previous acquaintance between the Head of Melamin's R&D Unit and the Department. The Head of the Department had previous experience in a business sector and was well aware of what kind of services a company needs from science. On the other hand, Head of Melamin's R&D Unit understood the motivation of science sector to enter into cooperation with industry. Mutual interest and acquaintance have been the crucial factors for launching and maintaining successful cooperation. What the Department sees as the most beneficial aspect of the cooperation is the ability to earn extra resources for R&D equipment. The possibility to work on specific topics through the entire process, i.e. from the definition of the problem, search for the theoretical solutions to developing a response in practice and testing it, is also important. In short, researchers at the university have the opportunity to test their ideas in practice and to increase the quantity and quality of publishable results. 3.3.2. Determinants and problems of cooperation Industry sector barriers. According to the Head of Melamin's R&D Unit, the main structural problem for strengthening science-industry cooperation in Slovenia is low R&D capacity of Slovenian firms. Consequently, PROs in Slovenia find it difficult to get interested partners in the industry sector. Low industry R&D activity and limited existence of in-house R&D units in the business sector is a significant barrier to science-industry cooperation because it is precisely these units which provide a necessary impetus and absorption capacity for cooperation with science. Another industry related barrier to more science-industry cooperation is prevailing short-term perspective in most Slovenian firms. Only a direct solution to immediate production problems is considered by the management as valuable research. They expect the cooperation to focus more on a day-to-day business and not as a process of opening up new venues for increasing competitiveness. Science sector barriers. Structural problems of science sector are no less important barrier to science-industry cooperation. Systematic marketing of own knowledge is not at all present in PROs and existing institutional framework at universities does not support cooperation with industry. The current system lacks incentives and infrastructure for establishing the links with industry. The interviewees suggest that cooperation between universities and firms has to be established and coordinated at the highest level, if cooperation with industry is to be developed. Current attempts are far from satisfactory. The organisational set-up of, for example, the University of Ljubljana with its decentralised, highly differentiated and heterogeneous members (Faculties) cannot be served by a common Technology Transfer Office, which would coordinate marketing of university scientific capabilities10. At best, the University should have some broad long-term agreements with larger Slovenian firms which are important R&D investors. This would ease building up of specific science-industry partnerships at lower levels. The lack of university level support was identified as a problem also in negotiating the cooperation contract. For a single relatively small unit at one faculty it is very difficult to competently negotiate specific legal and commercial terms of the contract. Objectives setting and mutual understanding of partners. Structural differences may result in problems of mutual understanding in setting of cooperation objectives, i.e. what kind of knowledge PROs can provide to firms. In a number of instances, the Department has been told by the firms that they received 'a lot of paper' with the results given at too theoretical level and were impossible to implement. Yet, one has to be aware that only the firms can be really specific in applied R&D work, developing innovative products for the market. Having in-house R&D department in a company is therefore necessary for successful science-industry collaboration. Productive cooperation between science and industry does not develop quickly or easily. Much of the success in cooperation depends on good trustworthy personal relationships, which are even more important in the cases where there are few institutional guidelines for a more formalised agreement. The Department - Melamin case is the best example of this. Still, good mutual understanding is not a substitute for a more formal agreement, where issues like ownership of research equipment, patents, commercial impact of new findings etc. are more precisely defined. 10 The University of Ljubljana established in 2007 an office dedicated to promotion of cooperation with business firms, called Institute for Innovation and Development (http://www.iri.uni-lj.si/eng/ ). Yet the Institute is still not seen by the members of the University as their representative in dealing with the business sector, since at times even competes for the same public research sources. The interviewees agree that the objectives of science-industry cooperation should be set by industry, but in cooperation with science. At the end of the day it is the industry who applies the innovation/ new technological solutions. PROs should assist the industry in setting these objectives. This, however, does not mean that science partner does not have its own cooperation objectives. The work should be shared and designed in a way that both sides are able to achieve their objectives. A clear understanding of each other's objectives, and respect for these, need to be a starting point in establishing the cooperation. The difference in the cooperation objectives of science and industry is clearly visible in the agreement between the Department and Melamin. The agreement specifies that all the knowledge resulting from the cooperation is the ownership of Melamin. The Department goes only up to the laboratory phase of product development, further on it is the Melamin who leads the game. The Department can publish all the results of its basic research arising from cooperation, but this includes only the data until the end of the laboratory phase. The Department always sends the scientific papers to be published for approval to Melamin. Melamin has patented some of its solutions. There have never been any ideas about joint patenting; the Department also does not have enough resources to assume financial obligations and risks of patenting and is not really interested in patenting. The interest of the Department is elsewhere, i.e. in getting additional financial resources, in publishing and in training of its staff. 3.3.3. Relevance of innovation policy measures Melamin has been aware of some of the policy measures, but has seldom applied for support. Similar complaint was voiced as in Case 1: irregularity, frequent changes in the con-ditionality, heavy bureaucracy, selection criteria not adjusted to business needs. On the side of the Department, criticism was directed to the insufficient support of science-industry cooperation at the University, where the established intermediary institution is not seen as adequate. Also, broader research system conditions (research evaluation criteria) are not supportive, but in fact often negatively affect the motivation for cooperation. 4. MAIN FINDINGS AND CONCLUSION The case studies confirm the propositions of existing literature as to the motivation for cooperation: a/ Frequency and intensity of science-industry cooperation depends on the extent and nature of firms' in-house R&D and innovation activity; b/ Absorption capacity of business sector is an important determinant of the intensity of cooperation; c/ Nature of in-house R&D has important impact on the selection of cooperation partners: the more basic research is the more room is there for PROs as cooperation partners, d/ Existence of critical mass of knowledge and quality research at the PROs, as well as PROS' flexibility to adjust to the needs of firms. С v В s 0 и и 43 '0 v 01 сл СО acf pi ao oh rt s л « Й с й 3 £ D n Б и •-ч ^ te Г) £ rt eer rt ^ « s ' Bi o d u ^ с d ^ se « ° TdRlU O <и н « Я "5 'S, <ц « £ 1 £ 1 ч ^ С О О < tsjt о Л Q <*8 rt e » s tU rd о Й « * I b « Sä . . (Л « 4CS щ "Я 3 'S Л и «su £ tni in h 8 .3 ä> | nl aw Г с ' Й « " q .2 о £ ^ s s » ö » ö s ftO ё Р § I o t d e N inc адЯ te ln д •а t s « SP о С boOi^ г„ 'S -Э 5J bp ^ g £ 53 Й д ^ С ^ с l cger и d U » д Д о h i; 0 о <и ^ Й "о <и « & ^ « £ -g rxoen Рч Sh .Д tß et nd lic eittust 8-S.S & pa. p » se e n ü S S rt Oi Oi Q ^ rt и e n s 0 Д Ё Su 2 rt hp i ад O 5ЯЗ n ao n t s Ц-н О ° d k co « & з л "л о mn H ^ a ć с й ö c И b<.H eps О P., o b £ £ f er e n с e « ^ 'I с ь, Й « „ „.2 Ы 3 £ i о В и Ё U £ S O S с ^ JH O -M Q « ee N > 3 C ^ « ^ rd та :з о g g 5 ад с. 3 с .3 ° тз -d с 3 3 £ Й «н-о-дП g ^ «j ere ^ rt s Ч-Ч qj К om P t« о uar rtsi a s 2 з ed > о p o £ > и eu dd Ž с Q« с ' ^ ^ d >н ^^ Ъ 3 eec 2 3^ har e me 3 gö ore Д ? IS n-ö Š ecn Й-Q л О о л rh Щ о ce oa -м (У -м s sn <и <и ^ ^ iu ст1 nu rt о и С и С о о e n £ S !3 rt Oi Oi t» In our cases, the motivation on the side of PROs is fully compatible with the theory: additional funding is the major motive, followed by access to specific empirical data which can result in publications. Also, a possibility to provide employment opportunity to graduate students is seen as important benefit of science- industry cooperation. The case studies show remarkably high consensus among the interviewees on the determinants, problems and other aspects of science industry cooperation, regardless of the fact that they come from very different industrial sectors. The interviewed partners are relatively satisfied with the cooperation and the results have mostly met their expectations. Still, they notice a lot of barriers to more fruitful and intensive science-industry cooperation and have expressed quite a pessimistic view of science-industry cooperation in Slovenia in general. They propose a number of changes, improvements and novelties in measures for strengthening science-industry cooperation. Below, we briefly present the most important conclusions and suggestions. Probably the strongest message of the cases is that increasing the number of companies with R&D activities is a precondition for strengthening of science-industry cooperation. R&D capacity of most of Slovenian firms is still low. To address this structural deficit, the government policy has been to offer R&D tax subsidies, yet this measure, while welcome by larger R&D investors (like Krka in our case studies), does little for the firms with no R&D units. Support to industry clusters was suggested by both the industry as well as science representatives. Clustering around the more propulsive firms may have a positive impact on other firms, which are their suppliers and customers. In the past, Slovenia had a measure co-financing cluster formation, but had decided to discontinue the support.11 Strengthening of firms' absorption capacity through in-house R&D departments and R&D staff is necessary to intensify the cooperation. Relatively small number of such units in Slovenian firms undermines the potential for science-industry cooperation. To address this, various measures have been designed by the government (mobility schemes, interdisciplinary research teams, young researchers from industry), but our finding was that these measures were not known to the business sector or were assessed as too bureaucratic. This inappropriate supportis of particular importance for the vast majority of small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), where one cannot expect them to have their own R&D departments. To increase innovation (cooperation) absorption capacity in SMEs without own R&D capacities, clustering around the more propulsive and R&D active firms may be promoted. Another possibility is to promote university spin-off firms for this particular function. On the science side, there is a problem of insufficient capacities for cooperation with industry. PROs need more flexible institutional solutions in support of specific needs of science-industry collaboration. Possible solutions are: allow/ promote establishing of spin-off firm(s) by PROs for business oriented R&D; promote short-term mobility to solve a particular problem in a company (or even to introduce a mandatory mobility for certain professions); introduce 'non-technical' content in the S&T university programmes, in 11 See Inno Policy Trendchart Report on Slovenia, 2008. particular economic, business and legal aspects of R&D. Improved and more transparent organisational set-up at the university level is needed, where systematic promotion of the science-industry cooperation should be undertaken at the top echelons; university promotion criteria should require practical experiences, resulting from work with companies. There is no systematic assisting of researchers or stimulating them in any way towards cooperation. Such initiatives are left entirely to individuals who have the ambition and personal affinity to work with industry. Promotion of science-industry cooperation is also not incorporated in research projects evaluation. Evaluation of researchers, research programmes and/or projects and public research organisations is based primarily on the number of publications and citations. This results in a lack of interest among public researchers for co-operation with business sector. Current institutional framework also does not take sufficiently into account the specifics of the industrial R&D units. Such units cannot compete for the research project funding at the same public calls with the public R&D institutions, if the most important criteria in the selection process are the standard scientific criteria. At least for the applied research co-financing, the positive experience of implementing R&D projects and translating them to innovation should be valued as equally important as publishing activity for the public R&D units. Overall, the cooperation with industry should have a higher impact on the ranking of the researchers. A common message in all analysed cases is that successful science- industry cooperation can only be developed gradually, from specific small initial tasks to a more comprehensive collaboration, most often on the basis of previous personal contacts between main actors on both sides. It is the industry who should have the main role in the cooperation objectives setting, but objectives should be set jointly in an atmosphere of mutual understanding, where both sides feel that the cooperation will help them fulfil their goals. The partners need to overcome the prejudice and move beyond stereotypes. The case studies reflect no impact of the intermediary institutions on science- industry cooperation. While Slovenia has followed the example of other countries with a more developed innovation system and has established technology parks and centres, incubators and development agencies (Bučar, 2010), it seems that their overall impact is still not felt by either community: business or the science one. This confirms the findings of Radošević (2011), that the focus of CEE/CIS countries on providing support to "linkage capabilities" is a policy failure: ... "current bridging policies are basically trying to link weak enterprises with unreformed universities and PROs. Links are only as strong as the actors they connect." (ibid; 376). Instead of copy-paste measures from advanced countries, Slovenia, as well as other CEE countries, needs to assess their own specifics and design measures in accordance with characteristics of their national innovation system. As identified through our case studies, strengthening in-house R&D capabilities of firms as well as reorganizing PROs so as to be better capable of cooperating with business sector is much more important in innovation policy then the support to intermediary institutions. This is especially relevant, if one tackles the innovation deficit of most SMEs by stimulating them to cluster around R&D active firms or spin-off firms or form joint research centres with PROs- like this was done in 2010-2013 period with centres of competence12. Also, more detailed research in the future should examine the R&D and innovation capability in business sector and evaluate the factors determining its strengths and weaknesses. Current Slovenian R&D and innovation policy seems to have serious delivery problems. The most important are the following: - Low visibility of measures. The interviewees show little or no awareness of the available measures for strengthening science-industry cooperation, especially the business sector representatives. - Heavy bureaucracy. The interviewees have complained of the bureaucracy accompanying R&D and innovation related measures. A significant mistrust is felt in the documentation required by the government agencies, asking for data not easily obtainable or of confidential nature. With the co-financing from the EU Structural Funds, the procedural details have gotten worse. Sometimes, the load of paper work turns away firms from application. Simplification, coordination and better visibility of the support measures is required. - More specificity in policy measures creation. The nature of science-industry relationship is determined significantly by the development level of a particular sector (observe, for instance, differences between food and chemical sector in Slovenia), by the size of actors in a specific area (both the business and research capacities are highly heterogeneous in different areas) and by the very size of the country itself. Therefore, design of policy measure needs to be done with Slovenian specific needs in mind and not copy-paste from best practice in a more developed environment. One such example is the university technology transfer offices, which can be highly successful in the USA, but have only limited applicability in Slovenia (or other countries) due to different university system. - The measures should focus not only on partnerships, but on support of capacity building as well. On one hand, increasing R&D and innovation capacity in business sector is needed, while on the other, strengthening the capacity for knowledge/technology transfer in PROs. - Importance of mutual understanding and gradual building up of cooperation. Personal contacts, informal relationships, building alliances not through formal contracts, but step-by-step by acquiring cooperation experiences are of crucial importance. Support to various activities, where representatives of the two communities, science and business can meet each other and openly discuss the issues related to their cooperation, can be a valuable instrument. - Policy stability and regularity of measures. Frequent changes in policies and support measures do not create a positive environment for cooperation. Stability in the innovation policy, in the evaluation criteria as well as in the support measures is what makes the framework more supportive to the risky undertakings like science-industry cooperation. 12 Within financial perspective 2007-2013 Slovenia with EU structural funds supported 7 centres of competence, where partners from industry formed joint research units with PROs to address their R&D needs. REFERENCES Arvanitis, S. & Bolli, T. (2009). A Comparison of Firm-level Innovation Cooperation in Five European Countries. Zürich: ETH Zürich. KOF Working Papers No. 232. Balconi, M. & Laboranti, A. (2006). University-industry interactions in applied research: The case of microelectronics. Research Policy,35, 1616-1630. Belderbos, R., Carree, M. & Lokshin, B. (2004a). Co-operative R&D and Firm Performance. Research Policy, 33, 1477-1492. Belderbos, R., Carree, M., Diesderen, B., Lokshin, B. & Veugelers, R. (2004b). Heterogeneity in R&D Cooperation Strategies. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22, 1237-1263. Bercovitz, J. & Feldman, M. (2007). Fishing upstream: Firm innovation strategy and university research alliances. Research Policy, 36, 930-948. Bolli, T. & Woerter, M. (2011). Competition and R&D Cooperation with Universities and Competitors. Zürich: ETH Zürich. KOF Working Papers No. 275. Bruneel, J., D'Este, P. & Salter, A. (2010). Investigating the factors that diminish the barriers to university-industry collaboration. Research Policy, 39, 858-868. Bučar, M. (2010). Diversity & Similarities in Firms' Innovation Strategies and Activities: Main findings of interviews and implications in the context of the Slovenian national innovation system. Country report within VII FP project Mycro-Din.mimeo. Bučar, M., Jaklič, A. & Udobič, B. (2010). National system of innovation in Slovenia, (Analize CMO, 4). Ljubljana: Faculty of Social Sciences, http://www.mednarodni-odnosi.si/cmo/publications.htm. Caldera, A. & Debande, O. (2010). Performance of Spanish universities in technology transfer: An empirical analysis. Research Policy, 39, 1160-1173. Chesbrough, H. (2006). Open Innovation: A New Paradigm for Understanding Industrial Innovation. In Ches-brough, H. Vanhaverbeke, W. & West, J. (Eds.), Open Innovation: Researching a New Paradigm (pp. 1-12). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cohen, W. & Levinthal, D. (1989). Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D. Economic Journal, 99,569-596. Cohen, W. & Levinthal, D. (1990). Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35,128-152. Conti, A. & Gaule, P. (2011). Is the US outperforming Europe in university technology licensing? A new perspective on the European Paradox. Research Policy, 40, 123-135. Criscuolo, P. & Narula, R. (2008). A novel approach to national technological accumulation and absorptive capacity: aggregating Cohen and Levinthal. European Journal of Development Research, 20(1), 56-73. Dasgupta, P. & David, P.A. (1994). Toward a new economics of science. Research Policy, 23, 487-521. D'Este, P. & Patel, P. (2007). University-industry linkages in the UK: What are the factors underlying the variety of interactions with industry? Research Policy, 36, 1295-1313. EC (2011). Innovation Union Scoreboard. ERAC (2010). Policy Mix Peer Reviews: Country Report SLOVENIA; A Report of the ERAC Policy Mix Expert Group; available at: http://www.arhiv.mvzt.gov.si/fileadmin/mvzt.gov.si/pageuploads/pdf/znanost/ang_verzija/Slovenia_ OMC_Report-FINAL_dec.pdf Etzkowitz, H. & Leydesdorff, L. (Eds.) (1997). Universities and the Global Knowledge Economy: A Triple Helix of University-Industry-Government Relations. London: Pinter. Eun, J.-H., Lee, K. & Wu, G. (2006). Explaining the "University-run enterprises" in China: A theoretical framework for university-industry relationship in developing countries and its application to China. Research Policy, 35, 1329-1346. Guliani, E. and Arza, V. (2009). What drives the formation of 'valuable' university-industry linkages? Insights from the wine industry. Research Policy, 38, 906-921. Inno-policy Trendchart report: Slovenia: 2008. Jaklič A. (Ed.) (2012). Evaluation of entrepreneurship and competitiveness policy in the period 2004-2009 with proposals of new measures and indicators as well as modification of existing ones (Targeted research project- in Slovene). Ljubljana: Ministry of Economic Development and Technology. Jensen, R., Thursby, J. & Thursby, M.C. (2010). University-industry spillovers, government funding, and industrial consulting. Cambridge, MA.: National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper 15732. Kremp, E. & Mairesse, J. (2004). Knowledge Management, Innovation and Productivity. Cambridge, MA.: National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER Working Paper 10237. Lam, A. (2011). What motivates academic scientists to engage in research commercialization: 'Gold', 'ribbon' or 'puzzle'? Research Policy, 40, 1354-1368. Lee, Y.S. (2000). The Sustainability of University-Industry Research Collaboration: An Empirical Assessment. Journal of Technology Transfer, 25(2), 111-133. Lundvall, B.A. (2002). The University in the Learning Economy. DRUID Working Paper No 02-06. Mali, F. (Ed.) (2004). The mechanisms and measures for transfer of knowledge from the academic and research sector within the new innovation paradigm. Report on the research project- in Slovene. Mimeo. Mowery, D. & Rosenberg, N. (1989). Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mowery, D. & Sampat, B.N. (2004). Universities in national innovation systems. Paper presented at the 1st Globelics Academy. Lisbon, Portugal, May. Narula, R. (2003). Understanding the Growth of International R&D Alliances. In Cantwell, J. & Molero, J. (Eds.) Multinational Enterprises, Innovative Strategies and Systems of Innovation (pp. 129-152). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. OECD (2011). Review of Slovenia's Innovation Policy. Paris: OECD. OECD & Eurostat. (2005). Oslo Manual, Third edition. Paris and Luxembourg. Perkman, M., King, Z. & Pavelin, S. (2011) Enagaging excellence? Effects of faculty quality on university engagement with industry. Research Policy, 40, 539-552. Radošević, S. (2011). Science Industry links in Central and Eastern Europe and the Commonwealth of Independent States: conventional policy wisdom facing reality. Science and Public Policy, 38(5), 365-378. Radnor, M. (1991). Technology Acquisition Strategies and Processes: A Reconsideration of the Make Versus Buy Decision. International Journal of Technology Management, 7, 113-135. RISS (2011). Resolution on Research and Innovation Strategy of Slovenia 2011-2020. Government of the Republic of Slovenia. Available at: http://www.arhiv.mvzt.gov.si/fileadmin/mvzt.gov.si/pageuploads/pdf/odnosi_z_javnost-mi/12.4.11_RISS_ANG_nova_verzija.pdf Van Looy, B., Landoni, P., Callaert, J., van Pottelsberghe, B., Sapsalis, E. & Debackere, K. (2011). Entrepreneurial effectiveness of European universities: An empirical assessment of antecedents and trade-offs. Research Policy, 40, 553-564. Venniker, R. & Jongbloed, B. (2002). When factory meets faculty: university-industry cooperation in the US. In Higher Education reform: Getting the Incentives Right (pp. 119-134). Enschede: CHEPS, University of Twente. Veugelers, R. (1997). Internal R&D Expenditures and External Technology Sourcing. Research Policy, 26, 303-315. Veugelers, R. & Cassiman, B. (1999). Make and Buy in Innovation Strategies: Evidence from Belgian Manufacturing Firms. Research Policy, 28, 63-80. Viale, R. & Etzkowitz, H. (2010). Polyvalent Knowledge and the Entrepreneurial University: A Third Academic Revolution. Critical Sociology, 36, 595-609. WEF (2007). World Economic Forum 2007 Global Competitiveness Report. Oxford,Uk: Oxford University Press. APPENDIX 1 Innovation activity and innovation cooperation by type of partners of Slovenian and EU27 firms in 2010 (CIS 7) Slovenia EU27 Innovation active firmsa as % of all firms 49.4% 52.9% % of innovative firms engaged in any type of innovation cooperation 44.7% 25.4% % of innovative firms engaged in innovation cooperation withb: Other firms within the firm group 30.2% 36.5% Suppliers of equipment, materials, components or software 66.8% 59.5% Clients or customers 60.6% 49.4% Competitors or other firms of the same sector 30.0% 26.2% Consultants, commercial labs, or private R&D institutes 49.3% 33.7% Universities or other higher education institutions 49.1% 42.2% Government or public research institutes 31.9% 24.1% Source: Eurostat, http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?dataset=inn_cis7_ Aug.lst, 2013). a/ Firms with any kind of innovation. b/ Cooperation with multiple actors can be selected. coop&lang= en (access APPENDIX 2 List of interviewees and partner institutions Case 1 Krka develops innovative generic medicines, i.e. generic medicines with value added, which are the product of their own in-house knowledge. It is by far the most important company in Slovenia as far as R&D activities are concerned. Company's R&D unit employs 550 researchers with EUR 88.3 million of R&D expenditures, which is 9.3% of sales (2009 data). We interviewed the Director of Research Department Aleš Hvala, Ph.D. For more on Krka and its R&D see http://www.krka.biz/en/about-krka/company-presentation/. Laboratory for Inorganic Chemistry and Technology of the National Institute of Chemistry Slovenia employs five researchers and three young researchers, employed on the basis of the so called Young Researchers programme of the Slovenian Research Agency (the institute on the other hand employs 285 people). Research activities of the Laboratory are concentrated on the investigations of porous materials (zeolitic materials, mesoporous materials and cement research) and on materials structural analysis (x-ray diffraction, nuclear magnetic resonance spectroscopy and X-ray absorption spectroscopy). We interviewed the Head of the Laboratory, Venčeslav Kavčič, Ph.D. For more on the National Institute of Chemistry see http://www.ki.si/index.php?id=117&L=1. Case 2 Emona RCP - Nutrition Research and Development Department, Ljubljana is a R&D unit of the enterprise Jata Emona and is involved in various R&D projects in the area of human and animal nutrition. It employs eight people involved in research, testing and development of different solutions for their own company as well as other companies. We interviewed Head of Emona RCP Matjaž Červek, Ph.D. For more on Emona RCP see http://www.e-rcp. si/o_podjetju_angla.html, and on Jata Emona http://www.jata-emona.si/about_us.html. Animal Science Department of the Faculty of Agriculture in Zagreb which employs thirteen people is involved in R&D projects in the area of genetics, physiology, breeding, selection and nutrition of animal and meat science. We interviewed professor Ivan Jurić, Ph.D, who is the main coordinator of the cooperation project Emona RCP. For more on Faculty of Agriculture of the University of Zagreb see http://www.agr.unizg.hr/en. Case 3 Melamin's R&D Unit employs 20 people, approximately 10% of company total employment. The work of R&D Department is based on: (i) development of new products, (ii) modification of existing products because of the demands of the market, legislation or other demands, (iii) co-operation with buyers, (iv) co-operation with production management and the inspection of quality. We interviewed the Head of company's R&D Unit Igor Mihelič, Ph.D. For more on Melamin seehttp://www.melamin.si/en/. Department of Polymer Engineering, Organic Chemical Technology and Materials at the Faculty of Chemistry and Chemical Technology, University of Ljubljana employs seven researchers and three young researchers, employed on the basis of the so called Young Researchers programme of the Slovenian Research Agency. We interviewed Head of the Department, professor Matjaz Krajnc, Ph.D.. For more on the Department see http://www. fkkt.uni-lj.si/en/departments-and-chairs/department-of-chemical-technology/chair-of-polymer-engineering-organic-chemical-technology-and-materials/ THE EFFECT OF HRM QUALITY ON TRUST AND TEAM COHESION IGOR IVAŠKOVIĆ1 Received: 21 May 2014 Accepted: 14 January 2015 ABSTRACT: The purpose of this study was to examine the relationships between the perceived quality of HRM, trust among athletes, their trust in head coach, and the perceived team cohesion in the context of basketball teams from four South East European countries. First, the modified version of HRM quality scale was verified on one sample of277 athletes from 36 clubs. Then the model was developed with the theoretical fundamentals of social exchange theory and tested on data from other sample of282 athletes from 37 basketball clubs. Results show that the perceived quality of HRM directly affects degree of athletes' trust in the head coach. However, it does not have a direct impact on trust among athletes, neither on team cohesion. However, athletes' trust in the head coach mediates the indirect effect between the perception of HRM and the perceived cohesiveness within the team, and it also plays the mediating role in the perceived HRM - trust among athletes' relationships. Keywords: basketball, team, HRM, cohesion, trust JEL Classification: L31, M10 1 INTRODUCTION The measurement of human resource management (HRM) effects is still a challenge for scholars from a whole spectrum of organizational fields. While the identification of practices which have positive impact on financial outcomes like earnings, ROA, ROE, etc. remains the most debated topic (Bowen & Ostroff, 2004; Ichniowski & Shaw, 2003; Pološki-Vokić & Vidović, 2008), less attention is given to HRM effects on behaviour and attitudes on micro and mezzo organizational level. An impact of the perceived HRM policies and practices on team level is from that aspect still an under-researched area, especially in the segment of sport clubs from transition countries, which operate in non-profit environment. Assessing the HRM effects on financial results is not the most appropriate in case of non-profit clubs, since they are focused (or at least should be) on other aims like top sport result, contribution to local community, growth of organization, etc. At the same time, cohesiveness and trust within the organization are often considered as the key leverages for achievement of a whole spectrum of non-profit sport aims (Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010; Paskevich, Estabrooks, Brawley, & Carron, 2001). Therefore, the degree of team cohesion and trust can have some kind of "common denominator" roles for HRM efficiency measures in non-profit sport clubs. This has been recognized among scholars, 1 University of Ljubljana, Faculty of Economics, Ljubljana, Slovenia, e-mail: igor.ivaskovic@ef.uni-lj.si which resulted in intensification of trust and cohesion studies among sport clubs in the last fifteen years (Dirks, 1999; Dirks, 2000; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010). However, while the majority of papers focus on the consequences of those two constructs, there is still a lack of research, which would try to identify their antecedents. Given the above, the aim of this research is to make a step further in the process of disclosing the so-called "black box" phenomenon in the HRM - trust and HRM - cohesion relationships. Our intention was to measure the importance of athletes' HRM quality perception and to identify paths through which HRM perception influences two crucial factors of team building. The major objective was to develop a framework for examining the relationships in the triangle of HRM, trust and cohesion, and then to examine the implications of the model using reallife data. This study will therefore have theoretical and practical impact. The first relates to the understanding of the relationship among observed variables, while (from practical point of view) the results should be useful to team managers in non-profit sport clubs in their ambition to increase the degree of trust and cohesiveness within their sport teams. 2 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND HYPOTHESES 2.1 The context of sport clubs in South-East Europe and HRM specifics When analysing a sport club, specifics of institutional and business context of particular organization should be considered. Despite the intensive process of globalization, we should be aware of the fact that sport clubs constitute a specific segment of organizations, which is more attached to its own local environment than other types. State regulations and tradition in a particular region play an important role especially in organizational process of sport clubs in Europe (Avgerinou, 2007; Fort, 2000). European sport clubs are affected by the fact that majority of European sport competition have preserved the traditional system, where the best clubs in the end of the season advance in higher ranked competition, while clubs with the worst sport result drop into lower level league. Consequently, there are no sport clubs with exclusive right to compete in particular competition which differentiates the so-called European "open" system from the system that is used in the United States. The "closed" system enables sport clubs to have a greater degree of certainty, while European sport clubs have to preserve flexibility, due to possibility of dropping into a lower level competition. At the same time, unlike in the United States, Europe does not have the system of athletes' development incorporated into the educational system. This means that every sport club also has the development function and produces young athletes who will eventually participate in top competitions. Consequently, the majority of European sport clubs have professional and amateur part of an organization. The dual nature results in mixed teams' structures, composed of professionals and amateurs (Boxall & Purcell, 2000; Auld & Godbey, 1998). Combination of them within a team can cause many difficulties, since one part of a team is being paid for its participation and the other part is not. Therefore, the achievement of trust among teammates and team cohesion seems to be more challenging for coaches and managements in those clubs. Sport clubs in Europe are traditionally, unlike their North American counterparts, closer to the non-profit sector. This is in line with EU Commission statement that sport clubs should offer sport opportunities at a local level and thus promote the "sport for all" idea (Petry, Steinbach & Tokarski, 2004). However, highly professional non-profit sport clubs that compete at the highest-level sport competitions are the specific of transition countries. This is the consequence of the unique historical development. In the centrally planned economies, all sport clubs were formed by national sports societies. Therefore, all of them were declared as non-profit and amateur organizations. The opening of athletes' market in transition period stimulated professionalization of top sport clubs. However, in most cases, they preserved non-profit legal status. The heritage of particular historical development can be noticed in the ex-Yugoslavia countries where the vast majority of sport clubs still operate as non-profit organizations regardless of their budget size or level of professionalism. However, it is important to stress that non-profitability does not prevent organizations from having a surplus of income over costs (Podlipnik, 2010). It only has to be reinvested in organizational activities. In practice, the financial flows are often difficult to control and due to poorly developed legislation, regulators often fail to prevent profit sharing among organizational members in good times. In the context of this research, non-profitability could increase the importance of observed phenomenon for couple of reasons. First, the organizational ownership structures in non-profit clubs are more complex than in their profit-oriented counterparts. Interference of numerous stakeholders usually complicates the decision processes and often results with the ambiguities in strategic goals and HRM policy. As some authors claim the absence of clear ownership, structure also increases the importance of trust and trustworthiness in those organizations (Greiling, 2007). Secondly, non-profitability usually causes higher percentage of volunteers who are not driven by financial motives (Škorić, Bartoluci & Čustonja, 2012). Therefore, overall perception of human relations within organization should be more important factor from the aspect of building trust and cohesion in non-profit sport clubs. Additionally, from the HRM aspect sport clubs represent a special segment of nonprofit organizations for couple of reasons. The most obvious is the fact that in sport clubs there are usually two separate parts of single HRM system. While the first is intended for administrative part, the purpose of other is to form competitive sport team. They differentiate regarding the role of head coach, which is significant in the second and usually minor in the administrative part. Therefore, when it comes to formation of sport team, sport clubs' managements delegate the responsibility and decision-making power on head coach, who, in accordance with the budget constraints, can choose between two sources of athletes. According to van der Heijeden (2012), sport clubs' teams can acquire athletes from youth selections (mostly amateurs) or athletes obtained on athletes' market (mostly professionals). Thus, from the aspect of team forming there are two crucial processes: development of young players and scouting. In line with Tuckman's (1965) theory of team formation, after "forming" phase, "storming" and "norming" phases follow. While the aim of "forming" is making a competitive team from the aspect of obtaining variety of skills, physical capabilities and tactical knowledge, the aim of "storming" and "norming" is to achieve as high as possible degree of team cohesiveness which produces synergy effects and enables athletes to achieve common goal. The ambition of this study is to test the strength of causal relationships in the triangle of the perceived HRM quality, trust and cohesion in non-profit sport clubs. Placing the latter in the context of social exchange theory, which has often been criticised for reducing the social interaction to economic transaction (Zafirovski, 2005), will enable not only evaluation of how the observed variables influence each other, but also testing the capability of this theory to explain social interaction processes in non-profit organizations. 2.2 The HRM-trust-cohesion link Every time an individual becomes a member of certain organization, he or she faces the HRM process. This is inevitable even in those organizations, which do not have formalized or planned HRM system. From the aspect of individuals, those practices and activities included in HRM system represent environmental factor, which affects their emotions, moods, feelings and should also have impact on their behaviour within particular organization. However, Alfes and others (2013) point out that every person is unique, so intended HRM system is not crucial from the perspective of HRM outcomes. The latter depend more on the fact of how the particular HRM system is being perceived among organizational members. This is in line with McShane and Von Glinow (2003) perceptual model, in which authors explained that every stimulator from the environment has to go through the filter of individual's perception, and only then it can have an effect on individual's emotions and behaviour. Therefore, in this study we examined how the perception of HRM affects two specific phenomena, which could be placed in the context of moods, attitudes and behaviour, trust and cohesive behaviour within the team. Team cohesion is the degree to which team members work together as they pursue the team's goals. According to Carron and Brawley's (2000) definition cohesion is a dynamic process, which enables a group to stick together and remain united in the pursuit of its instrumental objectives and/or for the satisfaction of member affective needs. It is especially desirable in the team context where members are interdependent and generate a mutual output. Numerous studies have already confirmed that the cohesion significantly contributes to a more efficient and effective functioning of organization, which is particularly noticeable in team sports (Hall, 2007; Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010). Previous researches have also confirmed the difference between social and task cohesion (Carless & De Paola, 2000). While the latter refers to the identification with the tasks and commitment to them, the social component refers to the extent to which individuals interact socially. Carron, Widmeyer and Brawley (1985) further divided the construct based on how individual members of a group are attracted to the group and how individuals are integrated into the group, which resulted with four aspects of cohesion, namely "Individuals Attractions to the Group-Task" (IAGT), "Individual Attractions to the Group-Social" (IAGS), "Group Integration-Task" (GIT), and "Group Integration-Social" (GIS). Until now, scholars have been mostly focused on measurement of the degree of cohesion in teams and its contribution to the final result (either on team level or on the entire organization). On the other hand, few studies also tried to identify the factors that contribute to emer- gence of cohesiveness. In that context, the construct of trust has been found as cohesion's accelerator from both (task and social) aspects. Especially strong connection was found between trust and task cohesion, which is the crucial dimension of cohesiveness in task-oriented groups like sport teams (Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Dirks, 1999; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010). Regardless of many similarities, it seems that trust is a bit more complex construct than cohesion. Trust research began in the 60s, when it was identified as a key element of teamwork (Argyris, 1962; McGregor, 1967; Likert, 1967). In the following decades, authors tried to disseminate studies and evaluate trust's impact on individual and organizational level (Roberts & O'Reilly, 1974; Kirkpatrick & Locke, 1996; Langfred, 2004). In the process of examining this phenomenon, scholars faced with the issue of its definition. Trust is obviously tightly connected to couple of other feelings and is directly influenced by many factors. Since it usually manifests in the risky situation, it is often considered as closely related to willingness of someone to take risk. Indeed, those people, who are more inclined to risk-taking, usually build trustworthy relationships quicker and easier than others (Mayer, Davis & Schoorman, 1995). Trust is also often confused with unclear distinction from cooperation. However, the latter has not the same meaning, as the cooperation can also arise out of the fear from potential punishment, which cannot be the source of trust. Further, trust is tightly connected with the construct of confidence in the sense that the individual must have confidence that the other individual has the ability and intention to produce it in order to develop trust relationship (Deutsch, 1960). On the other hand, someone can also have confidence because he or she does not consider alternatives, while the essence of trust is choosing an action in spite of possibility of being disappointed (Luhmann, 1988). This is emphasized by social exchange theory, which postulates that human relations are formed by the use of a subjective cost-benefit analysis and the comparison of alternatives (Blau, 1964). In line with this theory, the condition for trust is previous interaction of individual with other organizational subjects, where individual assesses more dimensions that form trust (Tzafrir & Dolan, 2004). The multidimensionality and domain specificity of trust has been confirmed in various studies (Zand, 1972; Zeffane & Connel, 2003). Throughout the years of examination, many scholars have tried to make a list of the most important conditions for its appearance. A short review of factors that lead to trust is presented in Table 1. Obviously the most often mentioned components of trust are ability, benevolence, and integrity. Besides the extra-trustor factors every trust relationship also depends on intra-trustor characteristics. People differentiate and some of them are more likely to trust than others. According to Mayer, Davis and Schoorman (1995) propensity to trust is a stable within-party factor that affects the likelihood this party will trust, while "ability", "benevolence" and "integrity" are dimensions of trust that depend on trustee. Adams, Waldherr, and Sartori (2008) added predictability as another factor of trust to this model. It has often been considered similar to trust construct, but willingness to take a risk and the vulnerability are not present in the predictability concept. Predictability also does not imply that one person will trust the predictable person more, since the latter can be predictable in bad sense. However, in general predictability enhances trustworthiness by reducing uncertainty (Lewis & Weigert, 1985) and is not directly linked to other three factors. Therefore, Adams, Waldherr, and Sartori split the trust of military team members into four dimen- sions, namely "competence", "benevolence", "integrity", and "predictability". Competence in this context represents the extent to which the person exhibits a group of skills, competencies and characteristics, which allow an individual to have influence. Benevolence, as the trustee's characteristic, is the extent to which the person is seen as kind, caring and concerned, while integrity is the extent to which the person is seen as honourable honest and having strong moral principles. Finally, predictability denotes he extent to which the trustee's behaviour is consistent and predictable. Table 1. Trust Antecedents Authors Antecedent Factors Solomon (1960) Giffin (1967) Boyle & Bonacich (1970) Kee & Knox (1970) Farris, Senner, & Butterfield (1973) Jones, James, & Bruni (1975) Rosen & Jerdee (1977) Larzelere & Huston (1980) Cook & Wall (1980) Lieberman (1981) Johnson-George & Swap (1982) Hart, Capps, Cangemi & Caillouet (1986) Butler (1991) Sitkin & Roth (1993) Mayer, Davis, and Schoorman (1995) Tzafrir & Dolan (2004) Adams, Waldherr & Sartori (2008) Benevolence Expertness, reliability as information source, intentions, dynamism, personal attraction, reputation Past interactions, index of caution (based on prisoners' dilemma outcomes) Competence, motives Openness, ownership of feelings, experimentation with new behaviour, group norms Ability, behaviour is relevant to the individual's needs Judgement or competence, group goals Benevolence, honesty Trustworthy intentions, ability Competence, integrity Reliability Openness/congruity, shared values, autonomy/feedback Availability, competence, consistency, discreetness, fairness, integrity, loyalty, openness, promise fulfilment, receptivity Ability, value congruence Ability, benevolence, integrity Reliability, harmony, concern Benevolence, integrity, competence, predictability Trust and cohesion are often considered as similar constructs, but close examination reveals a couple of differences between them. While cohesion is intergroup phenomenon, trust can be built upon a person, place, event or object, between two or more individuals (Johnson-George & Swap, 1982; Mayer, Davis, & Schoorman, 1995), between two or more organizations (Gulati, 1995), individuals and organizations (Zaheer, McEveily, & Perrone, 1998) etc. In other words, trust is context dependent phenomenon, which demands analysis from different perspectives, depending on relationship that is in the focus of particular research (Gillespie & Dietz, 2009; Laeequddin, Sahay, Sahay, & Waheed, 2010; Shockley-Zalabak, Ellis, & Winograd, 2000). Consequently, unlike cohesion trust construct can have several foci within the same team. This implies that cohesion is usually measured on team level, while trust is being measured in the context of various interpersonal relationships. Athletes within sport clubs also form trust relationships towards different positions in the organizational structure and sport literature suggests at least the differentiation between two inter-team relationships, namely trust among athletes and trust in the relationship athletes - head coach (Tzafrir, 2005). The second difference between cohesion and trust, which is in the context of this study even more important, is the fact that trust is a construct within individual upon other person or group of persons, while team cohesion is actually perception of how the group members behave within the group in relation with other members. Thus, trust can be denoted as emotional construct, while cohesion is more a behavioural phenomenon. Trust in other organizational subjects is in positive relation with behaviour at the workplace and is also connected with the HRM system in particular organization. This has been confirmed by Tzafrir (2005), who found out that trust stimulates certain HRM practices and vice versa. The literature also provides empirical evidences that HRM and trust have similar positive effects on work behaviour, including organizational citizenship, employee performance, open communication, team commitment and finally also on team performance (Dirks, & Skarlicki, 2009; Hempel, Zhang, & Tjosvold, 2009; Tzafrir, 2005). Indicatively, scholars also proved that perception of HRM quality and high degree of trust cause similar consequences and positively affect organizational success (Becker & Huselid, 1998; Delaney & Huselid, 1996; Huselid, 1995; Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010). However, it is still relatively unclear in which direction the relationship between perception of HRM and trust works. This causal relationship probably works in both ways, but the fact is that HRM policies and practices exist before individual becomes a member of a sport club. As Searle and Skinner (2011, p. 4) state: "HRM is about structuring the interaction of human beings within an organizational context in order to maximize performance". In other words, this means that HRM sets the context for building trust relationships. Indeed, the effectiveness of information flow from top management towards other organizational members depends on particular HRM system within the club. Therefore, this system is among else also responsible for maintaining good human relations in the organization, which includes building trustworthy relationships among organizational members. This can be presumed from Snape and Redman's (2010) definition of HRM system, which is according to them a set of interconnected activities, designed to ensure that employees have a broad range of superior skills and abilities. However, although usually the most important aim of HRM is to increase the level of competences and knowledge within organi- zation, it has much wider spectrum of effects. The latter are usually divided on three segments, namely: employee skills, employee motivation and empowerment (Conway, 2004; Wright & Boswell, 2002). Thus, the perception of HRM should not have impact only on ability, but also on other trust factors as integrity, benevolence and predictability (Jackson & Schuler, 1995). In line with that, it is reasonable to presume that specific HRM practices in basketball clubs in the role of "environmental stimulator" influence the perception of HRM quality among athletes, which affects their trust in other organizational subjects. Therefore, we set the first two hypotheses. Hypothesis 1: The perceived quality of HRM has direct positive effect on the degree of trust among athletes. Hypothesis 2: The perceived quality of HRM has direct positive effect on the degree of athletes' trust in head coach. In this study, we analyse the impact of the perceived HRM on athletes' trust in two specific trustees, namely other athletes and head coach. Since the latter do not have the same amount of responsibility for HRM implementation, it is reasonable to expect that the HRM impact will differentiate on those two relationships according to the trustee's responsibility for HRM implementation. Usually top managers are designers of organizational structure and strategy, including HR strategy (Creed & Miles, 1996). On the other hand, according to Lago, Baroncelli, and Szymanski's (2004) model of production process in sport clubs, head coach is the organizational subject with the highest degree of responsibility in day to day HR activities, which affect athletes, and has lot of manoeuvring space for shaping the nature of HRM system. Therefore, head coach should be (at least from athletes' perspective) the most important organizational subject for implementation of club's HRM policies, while athletes participate only in implementation phases as executors. In line with that assumption, head coach should get the largest part of athletes' gratitude or criticism for good or poor design and implementation of HRM practices. This consequently means that the perceived HRM should affect more athletes' trust in head coach than the degree of trust among athletes. Hypothesis 3: The perceived quality of HRM has stronger effect on the degree of athletes' trust in head coach than on trust among athletes. According to social exchange theory, organizations are forums for social (and economic) transactions (Cropanzano, Prehar, & Chen, 2002). Also in line with that theory team effectiveness is a result of interaction, coordination and collaboration between team members (Hackman & Morris, 1975), while trust is seen as the crucial factor in the processes of social exchange (Blau, 1964). In the context of sport teams, trust enables an individual athlete to have positive feelings and perceptions regarding other team members (athletes and head coach) and at the same time stimulates the subject to be open, reliable and concerned for others. This should also stimulate the positive cycle of reinforcement within the team, which could be the reason for the increase of team cohesiveness. The literature offers the explanation for the latter effect, saying that the degree of trust differentiate teams with high level of trust from those teams with lack of trust at the time of increased risk. In those critical moments, trust affects team members to accept their role and to perform even those unpleasant tasks that are necessary to win (Dirks, 2000; Mayer, Davis, & Schoorman, 1995). Trust indeed provides the belief that one team member can predict and understand others and vice versa, it reduces perception of risk, vulnerability, and uncertainty, which helps every team member to focus on his task in the context of teamwork. Those, who do not trust in other organizational subjects, work less effectively (Dirks & Ferrin, 2001). Positive link between trust and cohesion has already been found in previous studies (Hansen, Morrow, & Batista, 2002; Luria, 2008), and has been confirmed in examination of team dynamics within sport clubs. Mach, Dolan, and Tzafrir (2010) examined the relationships in clubs from various sports industries and found that trust among team members is an antecedent for team cohesion. Dirks (1999) made a study among NCAA basketball teams and also confirmed the positive trust - cohesion relationship. In line with that, we also expect that perception of team cohesion is going to be positively affected by the degree of trust among team members (athletes and head coach). Therefore, we formulate the fourth and fifth hypothesis as follows. Hypothesis 4: The perceived team cohesion is directly positively affected by degree of trust among athletes. Hypothesis 5: The perceived team cohesion is directly positively affected by degree of athletes' trust in head coach. In line our argumentation for previous five hypotheses, it would be reasonable to predict the positive relation between HRM and team cohesion relationship. The positive between those two constructs has already been indicated by previous studies. It was found that HRM and cohesion both correlate with the same constructs, namely: trust (Tzafrir, 2005), organizational success (Becker & Huselid, 1998; Huselid, 1995) and sport result (Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010). The positive link can also be explained with argument that the HRM process is responsible for maintaining good human relations in the organization with the mission to stimulate group of people to achieve common goal. The latter is very close to the Carron and Brawley's (2000) definition of cohesiveness, so we can assume that one of the HRM aims should be also an achievement of higher degree of team cohesion. On the other hand, the fact is that by now, there has not been found a direct relationship between HRM perception and team cohesiveness, only indirect causal link has been proved. In that context, we should not forget that perceived cohesiveness is the perception of how good do team members work together. Therefore, team cohesiveness is actually perception of behavioural consequence, which is not the primary effect of HRM quality perception. This could be the explanation that the perceived HRM quality - team cohesion relationship works indirectly through the third construct, which is in direct causal relation with both constructs. Trust is within person construct, which we expect to be predictor of team cohesion and at the same time the perceived HRM quality consequence. Since athletes' perception of HRM quality is shaped through every day practices, it should also be linked to attitudes that athletes form in relation with subjects that implement HRM, namely head coach and other athletes within the team. Previous studies also reported sig- nificant relationship between coaching behaviour and team cohesion (Gardner, Shields, Bredemeier, & Bostrom, 1996). Therefore, we propose that the perception of HRM quality positively influences athletes' trust in those subjects that are responsible for implementation of tasks determined by HRM policy, and that trust mediates this effect and stimulates the degree of cohesiveness, especially its task dimension. Thus, we suggest the final two hypotheses. Hypothesis 6: Athletes' trust in head coach mediates the effect between the perception of HRM quality and team cohesion. Hypothesis 7: Trust among athletes mediates the effect between the perception of HRM quality and team cohesion. All seven hypotheses form conceptual framework summarized in Figure 1. Figure 1. Hypothesized model of positive causal relationships 3 METHODS 3.1 Sample and data collection Recognizing the fact that each sport industry has its own HRM peculiarities, this research was performed on athletes only from male basketball teams. This improves usability of study results for basketball clubs' managements, and at the same time enables future identification of the differences between the characteristics among different sport branches. Since the objective of this study was to explore how the perceived quality of HRM influences the development of trust and cohesiveness on team level, the focus of research was on observation of the whole team as a unit. Before conducting a final research 30 interviews with basketball players were held to pre-test the survey questionnaire. Then, 108 men basketball clubs from Bosnia and Herzegovinian, Croatian, Serbian, and Slovenian national leagues (regardless of level of competition) were contacted by our researcher, who explained the purpose and methods of research. Participation was completely voluntary and anonymous; each participant was free to withdraw at any part of the survey. The data collecting took place through the whole 2013/2014 season, in each team at the end of practice, never immediately after a competition in order to avoid competition-specific biases. The questionnaires were completed under supervision of researcher, who stressed the importance of independent responses. Consequently, basketball players completed their questionnaires on their own without communication with their teammates or their coach. Finally, athletes from 73 clubs were willing to participate in research (67.6 %). Since each basketball team consists of 12 athletes, we can suppose that there are 1296 basketball players altogether in 108 clubs. 559 or 43.13% (7.66 in average per team) of them completely filled out the questionnaire. This represents sufficiently large sample according to HRM literature (Pološki-Vokić, 2004; Huselid, 1995; Becker & Huselid, 1998). The participants were in average 22.17 (standard deviation (SD) = 4.73) years old and had in average 4.81 (SD = 4.62) years of experiences with playing for current club in senior competitions. Similarly, high variation was noticed in the athletes' average tenure with current head coach. It averaged 2.45 years with the SD of 2.49. Due to the fact the new HRM quality scale was used in this study, the sample of 73 clubs was randomly split into two subsamples, and then the sample A was used to verify new scale, while second sample was used to test hypothesized model. Sample A (for the HRM quality scale verification) consisted of 36 (277 athletes) and sample B (for testing hypothesised model) consisted of 37 (282 athletes) clubs. Athletes in sample A had 22.05 (SD = 4.72) years, were 4.40 (SD = 4.52) years in current club and cooperated with current coach for 2.20 (SD = 2.43) years. Athletes in sample B were in average 22.29 (SD = 4.77) years old, played for current club 5.04 (SD = 4.44) years and were 2.66 (SD = 2.34) years with current head coach. 3.2 Measures Group cohesion The perception of cohesiveness among team members was assessed on the basis of a "Group Environment Questionnaire" (GEQ) developed by Carron, Widmeyer, and Braw-ley in 1985. This is a self-report questionnaire that contains 18 items and assesses four aspects of cohesion, namely "Individuals Attractions to the Group-Task" (IAGT), "Individual Attractions to the Group-Social" (IAGS), "Group Integration-Task" (GIT), and "Group Integration-Social" (GIS). Previous studies (Carron & Brawley, 2000; Li & Harmer, 1996) provided evidence of the scale validity and its usefulness in the sport team context. However, when analysing sport teams, scholars suggest the use of only two task components (IAGT and GIT) (Li & Harmer, 1996; Hogg, Abrams, Otten, & Hinkle, 2004), since previous studies among basketball and other sport clubs have repeatedly stated that the other two social components of cohesion have significantly less impact on the performance of the team (Carron, Bray & Eys, 2002; Carron & Brawley, 2000). Consequently, 4 out of 9 claims in our questionnaire measured IAGT, while 5 claims measured GIT dimension. Responses were provided on 7-point Likert scale anchored at the extremes by "strongly disagree" (1) and "strongly agree" (7). 6 claims were reverse coded. The internal consist- ency of particular cohesion scale for data obtained in this study was computed. Cronbach's alphas scored .77 (sample A) and .76 (sample B) (overall a = .77), which indicates that the cohesion scale possessed sufficient level of reliability (Nunnally, 1978). Then confirmatory factor analysis (CFA) was conducted on whole sample to test, if the scale really captures both task cohesion dimensions. Results did not support a single factor structure, since comparative fit index (CFI = .86), non-normed fit index (NNFI = .76) and normed-fit index (NFI = .84) were all below .9 threshold. Moreover, root mean squared error of approximation (RMSEA = .11) was above threshold of .10, which suggests that particular structure of the model doesn't represent a good approximation. On the other hand, a two-factor structure (CFI = .96, NNFI = .93, NFI = .94, RMSEA = .06) scored much better in all parameters. Therefore, we concluded that team cohesion in particular research was the construct of two factors. Trust For the purpose of this study, we used Adams, Waldherr, and Sartori's (2008) trust scale. It has been developed in the context of military units, which have been found to operate under similar conditions as sport teams. This scale was also preferred by basketball athletes who were included in pre-test survey, mostly due to inclusion of "competence" dimension, which is considered as crucial for trust measurement among task-oriented teams. Unlike some previous HRM studies (McAllister 1995; Dirks, 2000; Tzafrir & Dolan, 2004; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010), the ambition of this research was to measure the same construct on two different relations. Therefore, we used single questionnaire tool and the scales were modified only by adjusting referent person to "teammates" and "head coach". Responses were provided on 7-point Likert scale anchored at the extremes by "strongly disagree" (1) and "strongly agree" (7). Once again, we conducted CFA to test, if two trust relationships form two different constructs. Results did not support a single (CFI = .62, NNFI = .55, NFI = .61, RMSEA = .17) or a two-factor structure (CFI = .83, NNFI = .80, NFI = .81, RMSEA = .11), but obviously the latter achieved better score in all parameters. However, relatively low fit indexes indicated poor fit and the possibility that those two constructs form more sub-constructs. Since original trust questionnaire included four dimensions of trust, we conducted second order CFA. This time the model was formed of two-second order factors with four first order factors each. Results (CFI = .91, NNFI = .89, NFI = .89, RMSEA = .08) were not perfect, since NNFI and NFI scored below .9 threshold, but were acceptable on the basis of CFI and RMSEA. Overall reliabilities in cases of all trust scales were much above recommended .75 thresholds. Cronbach's alphas for trust among athletes were .91 (sample A) and .92 (sample B), while alphas for athletes' trust in head coach scored .94 (sample A) and .95 (sample B). Perceived HRM quality Perceived HRM quality scale has been built according to Gould-Williams and Davies's (2005), and Gonqalves and Neves (2012) recommendations. They have developed two different scales, which both proved high reliability and validity and showed applicability in various industries (Gould-Williams, 2003; Gould-Williams & Davies, 2005; Gon^alves & Neves, 2012; Alfes et al., 2013). However, since non-profit professional sport clubs in transition countries operate in specific circumstances, we wanted to develop special scale, which would be the most appropriate for capturing athletes' beliefs and attitudes in those organizations. Therefore, we organized a discussion between 11 basketball players and 11 experts from the field of HRM in sports clubs (5 head coaches, 5 sports directors and one sports psychologist). Each of them had at the time of discussion at least 5 years of work experiences in basketball clubs. Every member of work group got the Gould-Williams and Davies's as well as Goncalves and Neves scales, and then had to reconsider their statements and to modify them if necessary. Eventually every member came up with proposition of his measurement scale. The final list of ten distinct HRM phases was the result of combining similar phases: 1) scouting, 2) negotiating, 3) selection, 4) training, 5) game strategy, 6) game leadership, 7) performance evaluation, 8) financial compensation, 9) non-financial compensation and 10) way of leaving the club. Basketball players had to evaluate the quality of practices in each phase. They provided responses on 7-point Likert scale, where higher scores indicated a more positive response. The scale was anchored at the extremes by "the practices in this HRM phase are extremely poorly defined and poorly implemented" (1) and "the practices in this HRM phase are extremely well defined and perfectly executed" (7). In order to assure measurement of different constructs, we conducted bivariate correlation analysis between perceived quality of ten HRM phases (Appendix 1). Results showed that high correlations (correlation coefficient > .7) existed in the triangle of "trainings", "game strategy" and "game leadership", other significant correlation coefficients scored lower values. Moreover, only among those three variables the "variation inflation factor" calculation indicated potential for multicollinearity problem (VIF > 3). This indicated possibility that phases 4, 5 and 6 from athletes' perspective in fact form single HRM phase, so we conducted three confirmatory factor analyses (CFA) in order to test which structure of HRM construct fits best to our data. According to Hu and Bentler's (1999) recommendations results supported 8-factor structure (CFI = .99, NNFI = .96, NFI = .98, RMSEA = .07), where phases "trainings", "game strategy" and "game leadership" were aggregated in one variable (new variable was named "training and game leadership" (TGL)). On the other hand, single and 10-factor structures were found not to fit data well, due to low fit indexes (CFI, NNFI and NFI < 0,9) and high RMSEA ( > .10). Cronbach's alpha (.91) confirmed reliability of the "TGL" factor, while overall HRM scale alpha scored .83. Control variables Athletes, who participate in sport teams, do not operate in a vacuum. When analysing feelings about their teammates, we have to be aware of variety of factors, which could influence those relations. Of course, it was impossible to include all of them in this analysis, so we decided to take into account two, which could (according to social exchange theory) have the strongest influence on the causal relationship between perceived HRM quality, trust and cohesion: • Number of seasons in a team - the number of years that particular athlete has been member of current team. According to the definition of trust given by Doney and Cannon (1997), trust requires an assessment of the other party's credibility and benevolence. One party must have information about other party's past behaviour and promises, which usually takes some time. Thus, larger number of seasons that athletes participate in particular team, could enable each of them collecting more information about other athletes and head coach within this team; • Seasons trained by coach - an average number of years that an athlete in team has been cooperated with current head coach. Similarly as number of seasons in the club, number of seasons trained by the coach might be related to the degree of trust between athletes and head coach. 3.3 Data analysis Since data for all observed variables in our hypothesized model were collected from a single source, we had to consider the problems of common method variance and discriminant validity. In order to control the influence of common method bias, we decided to perform set of CFAs on both samples. Following the recommendations established in previous studies (Hu & Bentler, 1999; Hair et al., 2005; Alfes et al., 2013) we tested how the whole model with all latent variables fits our data according to three parameters: chi-squared, CFI and RMSEA. Overall the model exhibited good fit in both samples (A: x2 = 1693; df = 765; RMSEA = .05; CFI = .96; B: x2 = 1531, df = 765, CFI = .97, RMSEA = .05). Also all standardised regression coefficients in the model were highly significant at the .001 level. In the next step we conducted so called "common latent factor test" (also known as Harman's single-factor test) recommended by Podsakoff and others (2003). The new factor was included in the model and all variables were allowed to load onto one general factor. In this case the model exhibited extremely poor fit for both subsamples, which indicates that single factor did not account for the majority of variance in our data (A: x2 = 22285; df = 775; RMSEA = .23; CFI = .46; B: x2 = 20503, df = 775, CFI = .37, RMSEA = .28). In the next phase, the discriminant validity test according to Fornell and Larcker (1981) was conducted, in order to test if our constructs in proposed model are distinct from each other. According to Fornell and Larcker (1981) scale variables are enough different from one another, if each scale's average variance extracted (AVE) is greater than its shared variance with other variables in the same model. The test was conducted in both subsamples, which confirmed that all scales were distinct from each other (see Appendix 2 and 3). Finally, since the unit of observation in this study was team, we had to aggregate individual perceptions of team cohesion, trust and perceived HRM quality within each team. In order to justify the aggregation, we conducted an ICC analysis for each team. The latter uses one-way ANOVA test to compare within and between team variances and helps us to assess whether membership in a certain team leads to more homogenous answers (McGraw & Wong, 1996). The ICC coefficients ranged from .77 to .91, which suggests excellent reliability. 4 RESULTS Following the aim of providing a clear overview of relationships between perceived quality of HRM, trust and team cohesion we first conducted the correlation analysis for all variables on team level for subsample B. Table 2 presents the means, standard deviations, correlation coefficients and p-values for observed variables. The pair analysis provides a direct picture of the relationship between perceived team cohesion, overall the perception of HRM quality and two trust constructs. As expected, team cohesion showed strong correlation with trust among athletes (r = .51, p < .01) and trust in head coach (r = .55, p < .01), while the correlation coefficient with perceived HRM quality (r = .36, p < .05) was significant at level of .5. We can also see that both trust constructs showed significant positive correlation with perceived HRM quality. At the same time, we cannot claim that certain component of trust has significantly stronger correlation with HRM quality than others. Further, although both trust - HRM quality relationships were shown to be significant, it seems that association between perceived HRM quality and athletes' trust in head coach is stronger than HRM quality - trust among athletes relationship. Interestingly, except in the case of perceived HRM quality - "seasons with coach" (r = .33, p < .05), control variables did not show any significant correlation with main variables. However, as expected, they were in positive correlation with each other. In general, these findings are consistent with reports on correlation from previous research, which claimed that trust within the team is related to the construct of team cohesion (Dirks, 1999; Morgan & Hunt, 1994; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010; Costa, 2003; Schippers, 2003). Like Mach, Dolan, and Tzafrir's (2010) findings, our results also indicate strong positive correlation between trust among athletes and trust in head coach. However, correlation analysis did not provide strong evidence for the conclusions on the connection between team cohesion and perceived HRM quality. Table 2. Means, SD, correlation coefficients for sample B (N = 37) Variables M SD 1 2 3 4 5 1. HRM quality 4.48 .63 2. Trust among athletes: 5.57 .48 .31* a) Benevolence 5.86 .51 .34* .43** b) Integrity 5.64 .47 .10 .46** c) Predictability 5.20 .57 .29 .31* d) Competence 5.61 .58 .36** .58** 3. Trust in head coach: 5.85 .60 .50** .51** a) Benevolence 6.06 .55 .51** .48** .51** b) Integrity 6.02 .61 .44** .50** .53** c) Predictability 5.32 .62 .25 .56** .42** d) Competence 6.00 .87 .57** .37* .54** 4. Cohesion 4.68 .69 .36* .51** .55** 5. Seasons in club 4.42 2.86 .08 -.05 -.08 .16 6. Seasons with coach 2.77 1.52 .33* -.07 -.23 -.01 .37** ** P < .01 * P < .05 With ambition to understand the associations between observed variables better, we performed structural equation modelling (SEM) using maximum likelihood estimation in IBM AMOS 21, and followed recommendations of Bollen (1990), Hu and Bentler (1999), and Tzafrir (2005) for evaluating model fit. SEM was selected due to advantages over multiple regression analysis, mostly its ability to evaluate complex models. It enables testing model globally rather than coefficients individually and also enables inclusion of mediating variables into the model (Joreskog & Sorbom, 1993; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010). The results showed that initial model did not fit data very well. NFI and NNFI were below .9 thresholds, while RMSEA was above .10. Moreover, the p-value was below .05, indicating that the model is not well specified for this data set (Keats & Hitt, 1988). Therefore, we followed the suggestions of Alfes and others (2013) and tried to find alternative model, which would improve the fit. First we wanted to find out whether there is a direct link between the perceived HRM quality and the perception of team cohesion, so we tested Model 2, in which we added a direct path from those two variables. As Table 3 shows the model fit did not improve at all, rather the opposite. Moreover, the standard regression coefficient between the perceived HRM quality and the perception of team cohesion was insignificant, so we abandoned the possibility of direct HRM quality impact on team cohesiveness. For alternative Model 3 the direct path from athletes' trust in head coach to trust among athletes was added in order to test whether there was a direct association between those variables. This was suggested by Mach, Dolan, and Tzafrir (2010) and is in line with the argument that head coach has the most important role in process of team structuring, especially in the process of athletes' selection. Therefore, higher degree of trust in head coach and his/her decisions should lead also to higher degree in athletes that he or she selected. This time the model fit improved significantly and satisfied the conditions for the conclusion that the Model 3 is consistent reflection of the relationship between the perceived HRM quality, athletes' trust in head coach, trust among athletes and perception of team cohesiveness. However, regardless of good fit indices, this model showed that the standardized regression coefficient between perceived HRM quality and trust among athletes was not significant (r = .09, p = .547). Therefore, we removed this path from the Model 4, which caused the additional improvement of model fit. Additionally, we also performed SEM for all other alternative models of relationship between observed variables and have not found one, which would show better fit to our data. Thus, results suggested that the Model 4 shown in Figure 2 is the best reflection of the relationship between observed variables for this data set. Figure display standardized parameter estimates, statistical significance tests for each path and squared multiple correlations for dependent variables. Table 3. Structural Equation Model Comparisons - sample B Model X2(df) p CFI NFI NNFI RMSEA Initial 54.959(37) .029 .93 .89 .81 .12 Model 2 54.114(36) .027 .92 .82 .89 .12 Model 3 38.078(35) .331 .99 .92 .98 .05 Model 4 38.472(36) .360 .99 .93 .99 .04 Initial - hypothesised model Model 2 - added direct path from the perceived HRM quality to perceived cohesion Model 3 - added direct path from trust in head coach to trust among athletes Model 4 - direct path from trust in head coach to trust among athletes and erasing the path from the perceived HRM quality to trust among athletes Obviously, our findings undermined some of our hypothesized statements, but at the same time provided proof for some of predicted causal relationships between observed variables. Firstly, results confirmed strong influence of HRM quality on athletes' trust in head coach, which is in line with our hypothesis 2 and secondly, both observed trust relationships were found to significantly contribute to the perception of team cohesion, which confirms our hypotheses 4 and 5. Moreover, 46% of variance in team cohesion was explained by those two trust predictors. Further, the perception of HRM quality was found to have much stronger effect on athletes' trust in head coach than on trust among athletes as we had predicted in hypothesis 3. Although we did not find the direct impact of the perceived HRM quality on trust among athletes (which contradicts to our hypotheses 1 and 7) and team cohesion, Model 4 indicated that both causal relationships could work indirectly. It seems that the degree of athletes' trust in head coach plays the crucial mediating role in both cases. Figure 2. SEM results for Model 4 (sample B) .30 In order to verify our hypothesis 6 and to test other potential mediation paths, we conducted additional mediation tests. When there is a full mediation in the relationship X-M-Y (where X is predictor, M is mediator and Y is dependent variable), all paths (X-M, M-Y and X-Y) are significant. Addition of the X-M and X-Y paths to the constraint model should not improve the fit (Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010). On the other hand, when there is only indirect mediation effect, direct path X-Y is not significant. After analysis of each potential mediation relationship in the Model 4, we checked their significance with Sobel's test. The results presented in Table 4 revealed that HRM quality indeed affected trust among athletes and team cohesion, but only indirectly through athletes' trust in head coach. However, the effect was significant only at level of .05. We also found that certain amount of athletes' trust in head coach's effect on team cohesion was mediated through the trust among athletes. Sobel's test showed that this was a full mediation. Table 4. Mediation tests for Model 4 Mediator X Y Type of mediation Sobel's test Trust in head coach Perceived HRM quality Team cohesion Indirect z = 2.27; p = .023 Trust in head coach Perceived HRM quality Trust among athletes Indirect z = 2.17; p = .030 Trust among athletes Trust in head coach Team cohesion Full z = 2.28; p = .022 Finally, we can summarise that our findings supported 5 out of initial 7 hypotheses as shown in Table 5. Table 5. Hypotheses verification Hypothesis Finding 1 The perceived quality of HRM has direct positive effect on the degree of trust among athletes. Not supported* 2 The perceived quality of HRM has direct positive effect on the degree of athletes' trust in head coach. Supported 3 The perceived quality of HRM has stronger effect on the degree of athletes' trust in head coach than on trust among athletes. Supported 4 The perceived team cohesion is directly positively affected by degree of trust among athletes. Supported 5 The perceived team cohesion is directly positively affected by degree of athletes' trust in head coach. Supported 6 Athletes' trust in head coach mediates the effect between Supported perception of HRM quality and team cohesion. 7 Trust among athletes mediates the effect between perception of HRM quality and team cohesion. Not supported * Not found a direct effect, but there was an indirect influence of the perceived HRM quality on trust among athletes with the trust in head coach in mediating role. 5 DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS The purpose of this research was to develop and test the model of how the perceived quality of HRM affects the degree of athletes' trust in their teammates and head coach in the context of basketball teams and, further, how the relationship between perceived HRM quality and perceived team cohesiveness is mediated through trust. Results did not completely support our theoretical framework, but, on the other hand, they confirmed the general thesis that perceived HRM quality affects athletes' trust and has indirect influence on team cohesion. The findings confirm the positive relationship between HRM quality and athletes' trust and provide empirical support for the overall conclusion that better perception of HRM quality increases the degree of trust within teams. This is in line with previous findings on positive HRM quality - trust correlation (Huselid, 1995; Tzafrir, 2005) and with the thesis that high level of trust is related with the positive perception of HRM (Condrey, 1995). On the other hand, the results indicate that perception of HRM quality does not affect in the same manner trust among athletes and athletes' trust in head coach. The perceived HRM quality affects the process of trust building among athletes only indirectly, while trust in head coach is influenced directly. The latter also plays mediating role between perceived HRM quality and trust among athletes. Since head coach implements the majority of HR practices on day-to-day basis, this finding seems reasonable and is also consistent with the results reported in previous studies (Dirks, 1999; Dirks, 2000; Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010; Webber, 2008). From the aspect of trust - team cohesion relationship, this study confirmed that trust is indeed a strong predictor of team cohesion. Trust among athletes has been found to be in the tightest relation with the construct of team cohesion. At the same time athletes' trust in head coach showed significant impact on team cohesion, but only at the significance level of .05. Overall, we can conclude that higher level of trust among athletes is the strongest stimulator for athletes within the team to work more cooperatively in order to achieve common goals, which is in line with previous results that claimed trust is an important factor in the context of interactive teams (Costa, 2003; Dirks, 1999; Mach, Dolan, & Tzafrir, 2010; Schippers, 2003; Webber, 2008). 5.1 Theoretical implications The major contribution of this study is that it explains how the perceived HRM quality contributes to the two crucial trust relationships from athletes' perspective and how do those effects reflect on team cohesion. It also operationalizes a multifocal conceptualization of trust, offers detailed insight in the construct and explores the mediating role of trust between perceived HRM quality and team cohesion. This study provided additional empirical support to the growing body of empirical literature on the trust - cohesion relationships within sport organizations. At the same time, this is one of only a few studies, which examined the HRM - trust relationship on team level and is, according to the knowledge of author, the first attempt of perceived HRM quality - team cohesion causal link analysis. This study accepted the call of some scholars (Alves et al., 2013; Nishii et al., 2008; Den Hartog, Boselie & Paauwe, 2004) and tried to capture the perception of HRM from the perspective of employees and was therefore focused on experiences and subjective opinions, rather than on intended HRM strategies and practices from the view of HRM managers. We brought together two separate bodies of literature (HRM - trust and trust - cohesion) and demonstrated that trust is the important element of the link between the experienced HRM and team cohesion. This study placed the observed relations in the context of social exchange theory and confirmed that trust in direct superior plays the crucial role of mediator between the perceived HRM quality among employees and their trust in co-workers. Trust in head coach was found to be also the mediator in the causal relation between perceived HRM quality and team cohesion. Earlier research has shown that HRM has significant impact on beliefs of an individual employee (Sun, Aryee & Law, 2007; Allen, Shore, & Griffeth, 2003), and that the positive HRM practices positively correlate with trust within individuals (Tzafrir, 2005) and their perception of superiors (Alfes et al., 2013). In addition, several studies managed to prove the connection between trust on some elements of cohesive behaviour on individual (Mayer, Davis, & Schoorman, 1995) and group level (Mach, Dolan, & Tza-frir, 2010). With merging those arguments together, we develop some hypotheses in the triangle HRM quality, trust and cohesion relationship on team level. Our data suggest that trust in superior is indeed the crucial mediator between perceived HRM quality and trust among athletes, and between HRM quality and team cohesion. This new finding is certainly not a surprise and is consistent with predictions made in HRM literature which assumed direct positive influence of HRM on emotions and attitudes (Snape & Redman, 2010; Searle & Skinner, 2011; Alfes et al., 2013) and indirect effect on behaviour (Tza-frir, 2005; Allen, Shore, & Griffeth, 2003). This is also in line with the theory of social exchange, which suggests that where members of an organization feel that the decisionmakers within organization try to invest in them through the positive HRM experience, they are more willing to trust in their superiors. However, the only positive perception of HRM is not enough to directly influence the trust among co-working athletes on team level. The HRM quality effect is perceived through the construct of trust in direct superior, who implements the HRM practices on day-to-day basis and has influence on the rise of trust among co-workers and their cohesive behaviour. In the context of social exchange theory, this research provided proof of its usefulness within non-profit sport clubs. Study results also indicate that social interaction between two subjects within organization does not have only reciprocal effects, but externalities on other relations as well. This is especially important within organizational units where, like in sport team, it is difficult to distinguish individual effects on team task and where unit members share responsibility for success. However, the theory does not give satisfying explanation about why the perception of superior behaviour from HRM aspect does not have direct influence on the perception of co-workers behaviour from the aspect of cohesion. 5.2 Practical implications Several practical implications arise from this study. Although generally we can say that positive perception of HRM stimulates trust within teams, it is important to emphasize that the HRM quality effect on particular trust relationship differentiates regarding the HRM role that certain trustee has from the trustor's perspective. Therefore, the HRM -trust mechanism works different in each trust relationship. Since the head coach usually has more power than athletes do in determination of HRM nature, the effect on athletes' trust in head coach is bigger than the impact on trust among athletes. Obviously, in the context of sport teams, head coaches have important role in the process of HRM implementation, which is in line with claims of Bowen and Ostroff (2004). While positive experience of HRM by itself is insufficient to generate high degree of trust among athletes or high level of cohesiveness, athletes' trust in head coach helps to transfer its effects. This findings support the argument that head coach in competitive sport teams is much more than just direct superior, who only implements the HRM strategies and policies. Head coach has indeed a lot of manoeuvring space for shaping the nature of HRM, and has therefore the power to transfer the HRM effect on trustworthiness among athletes and consequently on cohesive team-work. This is in line with some claims (e.g. Torrington, Hall & Taylor 2005) that those employees, who do not trust in their superiors, will make ineffectual the work of any HRM system. Head coaches should be aware that quality of HRM practices that athletes experience on day-to-day basis appears to be a crucial factor for earning trust of their athletes. Moreover, head coaches should be aware of the importance of trust they enjoy among athletes within the team, because the latter is a generator of trust among athletes and team cohesion, which have been repeatedly proved as the stimulators of team success (Mach, Dolan & Tzafrir, 2010; Dirks, 1999). This is especially important for organizations where co-workers are in competitive-cooperative relations as is the case in basketball teams. Indeed, each athlete in a basketball team has to cooperate with his teammates, but in order to be in the position to participate in the game, athlete has to earn the minutes on the basketball court. Therefore, he has to prove that he is better than other teammates, if he wants to play more. In this process the head coach has the power to decide, who is going to get more playing minutes. If this decision is perceived as unfair, athletes will have less trust in their teammates and the vicious circle of distrust and lack of cohesion begins. Thus, from the aspect of within-team battle among athletes, trust in the head coach is a crucial characteristic of a successful team. 5.3 Limitations and suggestions The use of subjective data, which were collected on individuals' self-reports is usually perceived as a limitation, as it raises concerns about common method bias. However, in particular case of trust, cohesion and perception of HRM quality measurement we couldn't avoid that, and, moreover, the analysis eliminated the common method bias problem in particular study. On the other hand, many authors (e.g. Wright & Boswell, 2002; Alves et al., 2013) argued that self-report measures are actually the most valid measurement method for examination of HRM effects, since the intended HRM is usually different from implemented, and the individuals are best placed to report their own perception of HRM quality, their degree of trust and the perception of team cohesion. Secondly, our data were collected at only one point of time, which might limit the conclusions regarding the causal order in examined relationships. Thus, it might, for example, be also possible that athletes' trust in head coach leads to better perception of HRM. Finally, data were collected only among basketball clubs in four countries with similar historical background, which may hamper the generalization of results. In line with limitations stated above, we recommend further research on sport clubs over longer period of time, in different environments and from different sport branches. It would also be recommendable for future research to identify and assess which are other factors (beside perceived HRM quality) of trust among athletes and athletes' trust in head coach, and how does the strength of trust relationships differ among various groups of athletes (according to their age, playing time etc.). It would be certainly recommendable to examine, whether findings from this study are also valid for women sport teams. References Adams, B. D., Waldherr, S., & Sartori, J. (2008). Trust in teams scale. Trust in leaders scale. Manual for Administration and Analyses. Toronto: Department of National Defence. Alfes, K., Truss, C., Soane, E. C., Rees, C. & Gatenby, M. (2013). The relationship between line manager behavior, perceived HRM practices, and individual performance: examining the mediating role of engagement. Human Resource Management, 52(6), 839-859 Allen, D. G., Shore, L. M., & Griffeth, R. W. (2003). The role of perceived organizational support and supportive human resource practices in the turnover process. Journal of Management, 29(1), 99-118. Argyris, C. (1962). Interpersonal Competence and Organizational Effectiveness. Homewood, Ill.: Dorsey Press. Auld, C.J., Godbey, G. (1998). Influence in Canadian National Sport Organizations: perceptions of professionals and volunteers. Journal of sport management, 12(1), 20-38. Avgerinou, V., (2007). The Economics of Professional Team Sports: content, trends and future developments. Sport Management International Journal, 3(1). 5-17. Becker, B. E., & Huselid, M. A. (1998). High performance work systems and firm performance: A synthesis of research and managerial implications. Research in Personnel and Human Resources Journal, 16(1), 53-101. Blau, M. P. (1964). Exchange and power in social life. New York: Wiley. Bollen, K. A. (1990). Overall fit in covariance structural models: two types of sample size effects. Psychological Bulletin, 107, 256-259. Bowen, D.E., & Ostroff, C. (2004). Understanding HRM-firm performance linkages: The role of "Strength" of the HRM system. Academy of Management Review, 29(2), 203-221. Boxall, P., & Purcell, J. (2000). Strategic human resource management: Where have we come from and where should we be going? International Journal of Management Reviews, 2(2), 183-203. Boyle, R., & Bonacich, P. (1970). The development of trust and mistrust in mixed-motive games. Sociometry, 33(2), 123-139. Butler, J. K. (1991). Toward understanding and measuring conditions of trust: Evolution of a conditions of trust inventory. Journal of Management, 17(3), 643-663. Carless, S. A., & De Paola, C. (2000). The measurement of cohesion in work teams. Small Group Research, 31(1), 107-118. Carron, A. V., Brawley, L. R. (2000). Cohesion. Conceptual and measurement issues. Small Group Research, 31(1), 89-106. Carron, A. V., Bray, S. R., & Eys, M. A. (2002). Team cohesion and team success in sport. Journal of Sport Sciences. 20(2). 119-126. Carron, A. V., Widmeyer, W. N. & Brawley, L. R. (1985). The development of an instrument to assess cohesion in sport teams: the Group Environment Questionnaire. Journal of Sport Psychology, 7, 244-266. Condrey, S. E. (1995). Reforming resource management system: exploring the importance of organizational trust. American Review of Public Administration, 25, 341-354. Conway, E. (2004). Relating career stage to attitudes towards HR practices and commitment: Evidence of interaction effects? European Journal of Work & Organizational Psychology, 13(4), 417-446. Cook, J., & Wall, T. (1980). New work attitude measures of trust, organizational commitment, and personal need nonfulfillment. Journal of Occupational Psychology, 53(1) 39-52. Costa, A. C. (2003). Work team trust and effectiveness. Personnel Review, 32, 605-622. Creed, W. E. D., & Miles, R. E. (1996). Trust in organizations: a conceptual framework linking organizational forms, managerial philosophies, and the opportunity costs and controls. In Kramer, M. R., & Tyler, R. T. (Eds), Trust in Organizations: Frontiers of Theory and Research, 16-38. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Cropanzano, R., Prehar, C., & Chen, P. Y. (2002). Using social exchange theory to distinguish procedural justice from interactional justice. Group and Organizational Management, 27, 324-351. Delaney, T. J., & Huselid, A. M. (1996). The impact of human resource management practices on perceptions of organizational performance. Academy of Management Journal, 39(4), 949-969. Den Hartog, D. N., Boselie, P., & Paauwe, J. (2004). Performance management: A model and research agenda. Applied Psychology, 53(4), 556-569. Deutsch, M. (1960). The effect of motivational orientation upon trust and suspicion. Human Relations, 13(2) 123-140. Dirks, K. T. (1999). The effects of interpersonal trust on work group performance. Journal of Applied Psychology, 84, 445-455. Dirks, K. T. (2000). Trust in leadership and team performance: Evidence from NCAA basketball. Journal of Applied Psychology, 85.6, 1004-1012. Dirks, K. T. & Ferrin, D. L. (2001). The role of trust in organizational settings. Organization Science, 12(4), 450467. Dirks, K. T., & Skarlicki, D. P. (2009). The relationship between being perceived as trustworthy by coworkers and individual performance. Journal of Management, 35, 136-157. Doney, P.M, & Cannon, J.P. (1997). An Examination of the nature of trust in buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Marketing, 61(2), 35-51. Farris, G., Senner, E., & Butterfield, D. (1973). Trust, culture, and organizational behavior. Industrial Relations, 12(2), 144-157. Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. F. (1981). Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. Journal of Marketing Research, 18(1), 39-50. Fort, R., (2000). European and North American sports differences(?), Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47(4), 431-455. Gardner, E., Shields, D. L., Bredmeier, B. J., & Bostrom, A. (1996). The relationship between perceived coaching behaviours and team cohesion among baseball and softball players. Sport Psychologist, 10, 367-381. Giffin, K. (1967). The contribution of studies of source credibility to a theory of interpersonal trust in the communication department. Psychological Bulletin, 68(2), 104-120. Gillespie, N., & Dietz, G. (2009). Trust repair after organization-level failure. Academy of Management Review, 34(1), 127-145. Gon^alves, S. P., & Neves. J. (2012). The link between perceptions of human resource management practices and employee well-being at work. Advances in Psychology Study, 1(1), 31-39. Gould-Williams, J. (2003). The importance of HR practices and workplace trust in achieving superior performance: A study of public-sector organizations. International Journal of Human Resource Management, 14(1), 28-54. Gould-Williams, J., & Davies, F. (2005). Using social exchange theory to predict the effects of HRM practice on employee outcomes. Public Management Review, 7(1), 1-24. Greiling, D. (2007). Trust and Performance Management in Non-Profit Organizations. The Innovation Journal: Public Sector Innovation Journal, 12(3), article 9. Gulati, R. (1995). Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choices in Alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 85-112. Hackman, J. R., & Morris, C. G. (1975). Group tasks, group interaction process, and group performance effectiveness: A review and proposed integration. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 8, 45-99. Hair, J. F., Black, W. C., Babin, B. J., Anderson, R. E., & Tatham, R. L. (2005). Multivariate data analysis (6th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Prentice Hall. Hall, A. (2007). Sport psychology: building group cohesion, performance, and trust in athletic teams. Working paper. Capella University. Hansen, M. H., J.L. Morrow, Jr. & J. C. Batista (2002). The impact of trust on cooperative membership retention, performance, and satisfaction: An exploratory study. International Food and Agribusiness Management Review, 5(1), 41-59. Hart, K. M., Capps, H. R., Cangemi, J. P., & Caillouet, L. M. (1986). Exploring organizational trust and its multiple dimensions: A case study of General Motors. Organization Development Journal, 4(2), 31-39. Hempel, P. S., Zhang, Z. X., & Tjosvold, D. (2009). Conflict management between and within teams for trusting relationships in China. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 30, 41-65. Hogg, M. A., Abrams, D., Otten, S. & Hinkle, S. (2004). The social identity perspective: intergroup relations, self-conception, and small groups. Small Group Research, 35(3), 246-276. Hu, L. T., & Bentler, P. M. (1999). Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in covariance structure analysis: Coventional criteria versus new alternatives. Structural Equation Modeling, 6(1), 1-55. Huselid, M. (1995). The impact of human resource management practices on turnover, productivity, and corporate financial performance. Academy of Management Journal, 38(3), 635-672. Ichniowski, C. & Shaw, K. (2003). Beyond incentive pay: Insiders' estimates of the value of complementary human resource management practices. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 155-180. Jackson, S.E. & Schuler, R.S. (1995). Understanding Human Resource Management in the Context of Organizations and their Environments. Annual Review of Psychology, 46(1), 237-64. Jöreskog, K. G., & Sörbom, D. (1993). LISREL 8: Structural equation modeling with the SIMPLIS command language. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Johnson-George, C., & Swap, W. (1982). Measurement of specific interpersonal trust: Construction and validation of a scale to assess trust in a specific other. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 43, 1306-1317. Jones, A. P., James, L. R., & Bruni, J. R. (1975). Perceived leadership behavior and employee confidence in the leader as moderated by job involvement. Journal of Applied Psychology, 60(1), 146-149. Keats, B. W., & Hitt, M.A. (1988). A causal model of linkages among environmental dimensions, macro organizational characteristics, and performance. The Academy of Management Journal, 31, 570-598. Kee, H. W., & Knox, R. E. (1970). Conceptual and methodological considerations in the study of trust. Journal of Conflict Resolution. 14(3), 357-366. Kirkpatrick, S., & Locke, E. (1996). Direct and indirect effects of three core charismatic leadership components on performance and attitudes. Journal of Applied Psychology, 81(1), 36-51. Laeequddin, M., Sahay, B. S., Sahay, V., & Waheed, K. A. (2010). Measuring trust in supply chain partners' relationships. Measuring Business Excellence, 14(3), 53-69. Lago, U., Baroncelli, A., Szymanski, S. (2004). Il Business del calcio. Milano: Egea. Langfred, C. W. (2004). Too much of a good thing? The negative effects of high trust and autonomy in self-managing teams. Academy of Management Journal, 47(3): 385-399. Larzelere, R., & Huston, T. (1980). The dyadic trust scale: Toward understanding interpersonal trust in close relationships. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 42(3), 595-604. Lewis, J., & Weigert, A. (1985). Trust as a social reality. Social Forces, 63(4), 967-985. Li, F., & Harmer, P. (1996). Confirmatory factor analysis of the Group Environment Questionnaire with an intercollegiate sample. Journal of Sport and Exercise Psychology, 18, 49-63. Lieberman, J. K. (1981). The litigious society. New York: Basic Books. Likert, R. (1967). The human organization: Its management and value. New York: McGraw-Hill. Luhmann, Niklas (1988) 'Familiarity, Confidence, Trust: Problems and Alternatives', in Diego Gambetta (Ed.) Trust: Making and Breaking of Cooperative Relations (pp. 94-107). Oxford: Blackwell. Luria, G. (2008). Climate strenght - how leaders form consensus. Leadership Quaterly, 19, 42-53. Mach, M., Dolan, S., & Tzafrir, S. (2010). The differential effect of team members' trust on team performance: The mediation role of team cohesion. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 83, 771-794. Mayer, R. C., Davis, J. H., & Schoorman, F. D. (1995). An integrative model of organizational trust. Academy of Management Review, 20(3), 709 -734. McAllister, D. (1995). Affect and cognition based trust as foundations for interpersonal cooperation in organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1), 24-59. McGraw, K. O., & Wong, S. P. (1996). Forming inferences about some intraclass correlation coefficients. Psychological Methods, 1(4), 30-46. McGregor, D. (1967). The professional manager (W.G. Bennis, & C. McGregor, Eds). New York: McGraw-Hill. McShane, S. L. & Von Glinow, M. A. Y. (2003). Organizational behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill. Morgan, R. M., & Hunt, S. D. (1994). The commitment-trust theory of relationship marketing. Journal of Marketing, 58(3), 20-38. Nishii, L. H., Lepak, D. P., & Schneider, B. (2008). Employee attributions of the "why" of HR practices: Their effects on employee attitudes and behaviors, and customer satisfaction. Personnel Psychology, 61(3), 503-545. Nunnally, J. C. (1978). Psychometric theory (2nd edition). New York: McGraw-Hill. Paskevich, D. M., Estabrooks, P. A., Brawley, L. R., & Carron, A. V. (2001). Group cohesion in sport and exercise. In R. N. Singer, H. A. Hausenblas, & C. M. Janelle (Eds.). Handbook of Sport Psychology (2nd ed.) (pp.472-494). New York: John Wiley & Sons. Petry, K., Steinbach, D, & Tokarski, W. (2004). Sport systems in the countries of the European Union: similarities and differences. European Journal for Sport and Society, 1(1), 15-21. Podlipnik, J. (2010). Pravni in davčni status športnih klubov. Ljubljana: Pravna fakulteta, Univerza v Ljubljani. Pološki-Vokić, N. (2004). Menađament ljudskih potencijala u velikim hrvatskim poduzećima. Ekonomski pregled, 55(5-6), 455-478. Retrieved from: hrcak.srce.hr/file/24714 Pološki-Vokić, N., & Vidović, M. (2008). HRM as a significant factor for achieving competitiveness through people: the Croatian case. International Advances in Economic Research, 14(3), 303-315. Roberts, K. H., & O'Reilly, C. A. (1974). Measuring organizational communication. Journal of Applied Psychology, 59, 321-326. Rosen, B., & Jerdee, T. H. (1977). Influence of subordinate characteristics on trust and use of participative decision strategies in a management simulation. Journal of Applied Psychology, 62(5) 628-631. Schippers, M. C. (2003). Reflexivity in teams. Ridderkerk: Ridderprint. Searle, R.H. & Skinner, D. (2011). Trust and human resource management. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Shockley-Zalabak, P., Ellis, K., & Winograd, G. (2000). Organizational trust: What it means, why it matters. Organization Development Journal, 18(4), 35-48. Sitkin, S. B, & Roth, N. L. (1993). Explaining the limited effectiveness of legalistic "remedies" for trust/distrust. Organization Science, 4(3), 367-392. Snape, E., & Redman, T. (2010). HRM practices, organizational citizenship behaviour, and performance: A multi-level analysis. Journal of Management Studies, 47, 1219-1247. Solomon, L. (1960). The influence of some types of power relationships and game strategies upon the development of interpersonal trust. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 61(2), 223-230. Sun, L.-Y., Aryee, S., & Law, K. S. (2007). High performance human resource practices, citizenship behavior, and organizational performance: A relational perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 50(3), 558-577. Škorić, S., Bartoluci, M, & Čustonja, Z. (2012). Public financing in Croatian sport. Financial Theory & Practice, 36(2), 109-227. Tabachnick, B.G., & Fidell, L.S. (2007). Using multivariate statistics (5th edition). New York: Allyn and Bacon. Torrington, D, Hall, L., & Taylor, S. (2005). Human Resource Management. Prentice Hall/Financial Times: Essex. Tuckman, B. W. (1965). Developmental sequence in small groups, Psychological Bulletin, 63(6), 384-399. Tzafrir, S. S., & Dolan, S. L. (2004). Trust me: a scale for measuring manager-employee trust, management research. The Journal of the Iberoamerican Academy of Management, 2(2), 115 - 132. Tzafrir, S. S. (2005). The relationship between trust, HRM practices and firm performance. International Journal of Human Resource Management, 16(9), 1600-1622. van der Heijden, L. (2012). Does HRM matter for professional soccer organizations? A research on the HRM-Performance relationship for PSOs. University of Twente: School of Management and Governance. Webber, S. S. (2008). Development of cognitive and affective trust in teams. A longitudinal study. Small Group Research, 39, 746-769. Wheaton, B., Muthen, B., Alwin, D. F., & Summers, G. (1977). Assessing reliability and stability in panel models. Sociological Methodology, 8(1), 84-136. Wright, P. M., & Boswell, W. R. (2002). Desegregating HRM: A review and synthesis of micro and macro human resource management research. Journal of Management, 28(3), 247-276. Zafirovski, M. (2005). Social exchange theory under scrutiny: a positive critique of its economic-behaviorist formulations. Electronic Journal of Sociology. Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V. (1998). Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Science 9, 141-159. Zand, D. E. (1972). Trust and managerial problem solving. Administrative Science Quarterly, 17(2), 229-239. Zeffane, R., & Connell, J. (2003). Trust and HRM in the New Millenium. International Journal of Human Resource Management, 14(1), 3-11. APPENDIX 1 Means, SD and correlation coefficients between perceived quality of HRM phases (N = 277) Variables M SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1. Scouting 4.7 1.62 2. Negotiating 4.2 1.72 .56 3. Selection 5.0 1.32 .57 .59 4. Trainings 5.4 1.43 .54 .42 .58 5. Game strategy 5.4 1.34 .54 .45 .56 .79 6. Game leadership 5.4 1.42 .45 .32 .50 .78 .78 7. Evaluation of performance 5.0 1.29 .40 .38 .54 .57 .64 .66 8. Financial compensation 3.3 1.89 .32 .54 .39 .28 .31 .26 .34 9. Non-financial compensation 3.8 1.86 .25 .43 .30 .28 .34 .29 .32 .52 10. Way of leaving the club 4.0 1.71 .19 .34 .20 .10* .18 .10* .16 .37 .37 All correlation coefficients are significant at the level of .01 except * APPENDIX 2 Means, SD, correlation coefficients and AVE for subsample A (N = 277) Variables M SD 1 2 3 4 5 1. Perceived HRM quality 4.44 1.12 AVE = .64 2. Trust among athletes 5.56 0.87 .43** AVE = .82 3. Trust in head coach 5.79 1.08 .51** .51** AVE = .81 4. Perceived cohesiveness 4.85 1.03 .29** .44** .43** AVE = .71 5. Seasons in team 4.40 4.52 -.02 .06 .10 .12 6. Seasons with current 2.20 2.43 .21 .06 .15* .12 .37** head coach ** P < .01 * P < .05 APPENDIX 3 Means, SD, correlation coefficients and AVE for subsample B (N = 282) Variables M SD 1 2 3 4 5 1. Perceived HRM quality 4.43 1.27 AVE = .55 2. Trust among athletes 5.52 0.81 .41** AVE = .80 3. Trust in head coach 5.77 1.03 .45** .50** AVE = .82 4. Perceived cohesiveness 4.66 1.01 .18** .37** .36** AVE = .62 5. Seasons in team 5.04 4.44 -.19** .08 .09 .01 6. Seasons with current 2.66 2.34 -.02 -.04 .00 -.10 .50** head coach ** P < .01 * P < .05 E/B/R POVZETKI V SLOVENSKEM JEZIKU DEACCESSIONING AND AGENCY COSTS OF FREE CASH FLOW IN MANAGER'S HANDS: A FORMAL MODEL ODSVOJITEV MUZEJSKI DEL IN AGENTSKI STROŠKI PROSTEGA DENARNEGA TOKA V ROKAH MANAGERJEV: FORMALNI MODEL ANDREJ SRAKAR POVZETEK: Na problem agentskih stroškov prostega denarnega toka v rokah managerjev sta prva opozorila Easterbrook in Jensen. V prispevku predstavljamo enega prvih poskusov formalnega, matematičnega modeliranja tega problema v luči podobne situacije, s katero se srečujejo managerji v muzejih pri odločanju o prodaji oz. odsvojitvi muzejskih del v njihovih zbirkah. V prispevku pokažemo, da odsvojitev muzejskih del vedno vodi do različnih oblik agentskih stroškov za muzej. Ugotovitev lahko neposredno prenesemo na primer katerekoli druge neprofitne organizacije in njenega premoženja. Izziv nadaljnjemu raziskovanju pa je dokaz splošne trditve tudi v primeru zasebnih, k dobičku usmerjenih podjetij. Ključne besede: odsvojitev muzejskih del, agentski stroški, prosti denarni tok, neprofitne organizacije ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF INTRODUCTION OF AN ADDITIONAL CARBON TAX ON THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY CONSIDERING DIFFERENT FORMS OF RECYCLING ANALIZA VPLIVA UVEDBE DODATNEGA DAVKA NA CO2 NA SLOVENSKO GOSPODARSTVO OB UPOŠTEVANJU RAZLIČNIH OBLIK RECIKLIRANJA ALEKSANDAR KEŠELJEVIĆ, MATJAŽ KOMAN POVZETEK: Članek opisuje nekaj okoljskih in ekonomskih posledic zaradi dodatnega davek na CO2 v vrednosti 15 EUR /1CO2 v Sloveniji v obdobju 2012-2030, da bi ugotoviti, ali je prinesla dvojno dividendo. Avtorja analizirata (z uporabo E3ME modela) različne oblike recikliranja prihodkov z zmanjšanjem prispevkov za socialno varnost, bodisi delodajalcev ali zaposlenih ali z zmanjšanjem javnofinančnega primanjkljaja, da bi opredelili optimalne fiskalne instrumente za izboljšanje okoljske in ekonomske blaginje (dvojne dividende). Avtorja v članku, prikazanem v luči takšne politike, trdita, da ima zmanjšanje prispevka za socialno varnost delavca ugodnejši učinek zmanjšanje delodajalčevega prispevka za socialno varnost. Ključne besede: zeleni davek, reforma okoljskih dajatev, dvojna dividenda, davek na CO2, recikliranje, E3ME model THE RELEVANCE OF EMPLOYEE-RELATED RATIOS FOR EARLY DETECTION OF CORPORATE CRISES USTREZNOST ZAPOSLENEGA - POVEZANO RAZMERJE ZA ZGODNJE ODKRIVANJE KORPORATIVNE KRIZE MARIO SITUM POVZETEK: Namen študije je bil analizirati, ali imajo razmerja povezana z zaposlenimi, ki izhajajo iz računovodskih izkazov, predpostavljeno napovedno moč za zgodnje odkrivanje korporativne krize in stečajev. Na osnovi pregledane literature, je mogoče videti, da še ni bilo veliko pozornosti usmerjene v to nalogo, kar kaže, da je nadaljnja raziskava utemeljena. Za empirične raziskovalne namene je bila uporabljena baza podatkov o avstrijskih podjetij v letih 2003-2005, da bi razvili multivariatne linearne diskriminantne funkcije za razvrščanje podjetij v dve skupini; tista, ki so v stečaju in tista, ki niso in za odkrivanje prispevka razmerja povezanega z zaposlenimi pri pojasnjevanju zakaj podjetja propadajo. Več razmerij iz predhodne raziskave je bili uporabljenih pri možnih napovedih. Poleg tega so bila analizirana tudi druga ločena razmerja, vključno s podatkom o povezavi z zaposlenimi. Rezultati študije kažejo, da medtem, ko razmerja zaposlenih ne morejo prispevati k izboljšanju učinkovitosti razvrščanja napovedovalnih modelov, znaki teh razmerij znotraj diskriminantnih funkcij pokažejo pričakovane rezultate. Učinkovita raba zaposlenih se zdi, da ima pomembno vlogo pri zmanjševanju verjetnosti stečaja. Poleg tega sta bili odkriti dve razmerji na zaposlenega, ki se lahko uporabita kot približka za velikost podjetja. To ni bilo opredeljeno v prejšnjih študijah za ta dejavnik. Kjučne besede: predvidevanje stečaja, indikatorji krize, diskriminantna analiza SCIENCE-INDUSTRY COOPERATION IN SLOVENIA: DETERMINANTS OF SUCCESS SODELOVANJE MED ZNANOSTJO IN INDUSTRIJO V SLOVENIJI: DEJAVNIKI USPEHA MAJA BUČAR, MATIJA ROJEC POVZETEK: Članek analizira ovire sodelovanja med znanostjo in industrijo v Sloveniji s tremi podrobnimi študijami primerov. Vsak primer obravnava obe strani, industrijo (podjetja) in znanost (univerzo/raziskovalni inštitut). Študije primerov potrjujejo domnevo, da je odsotnost podjetij z lastno R & R dejavnostjo glavni strukturni primanjkljaj za več sodelovanja med znanostjo in industrijo. Krepitev oddelkov podjetij z lastnimi oddelki in zaposlenimi v R & R ter grozdenja podjetij okoli najbolj propulzivnih, je predpogoj za boljše sodelovanje znanosti in industrije. Uspešno sodelovanje med znanostjo in industrijo se lahko razvija le postopoma, največkrat na osnovi preteklih osebnih stikov med glavnimi akterji na obeh straneh. Študije primerov ne kažejo vpliva posredniških institucij za sodelovanje med znanostjo in industrijo. Ključne besede: sodelovanje znanosti in industrije, Slovenija, študija primera THE EFFECT OF HRM QUALITY ON TRUST AND TEAM COHESION UČINEK KAKOVOSTI HRM NA ZAUPANJU IN KOHEZIJO EKIPE IGOR IVAŠKOVIĆ POVZETEK: Namen raziskave je bil preučiti odnose med zaznano kakovostjo HRM, zaupanjem med športniki, njihovo zaupanje glavnemu trenerju in zaznano ekipno kohezijo v okviru košarkarskih ekip iz štirih državah jugovzhodne Evrope. Spremenjena različica HRM lestvice kakovosti je bila preverjena na prvem vzorcu 277 športnikov iz 36 klubov. Nato pa je bil model razvit s teoretičnimi osnovami teorije družbene menjave in preizkušen na podatkih drugega vzorca 282 športnikov iz 37 košarkarskih klubov. Rezultati kažejo, da zaznana kakovost človeških virov neposredno vpliva na stopnjo zaupanja športnikov v trenerja. Vendar to nima neposrednega vpliva na zaupanje med športniki, niti na ekipno kohezijo. Vendar zaupanje športnikov v glavnega trenerja posreduje posredni učinek med percepcijo HRM in zaznano kohezijo v ekipi, in predvaja tudi posredniško vlogo pri zaznanem HRM - zaupanje med športniki. Ključne besede: košarka, ekipa, HRM, kohezija, zaupanje