Volume 24 Issue 1 Article 4 March 2022 Innovation and Productivity: Is Learning by Doing Over? Ružica Bukša Tezzele Juraj Dobrila University of Pula, Faculty of Economics and Tourism "Dr. Mijo Mirković", PhD Candidate, Pula, Croatia, ruzica.buksa@gmail.com Follow this and additional works at: https://www.ebrjournal.net/home Part of the Labor Economics Commons Recommended Citation Bukša Tezzele, R. (2022). Innovation and Productivity: Is Learning by Doing Over?. Economic and Business Review, 24(1). https://doi.org/10.15458/2335-4216.1297 This Original Article is brought to you for free and open access by Economic and Business Review. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic and Business Review by an authorized editor of Economic and Business Review. ORIGINAL ARTICLE Innovation and Productivity: Is Learning by Doing Over? Ruzica Buksa Tezzele Juraj Dobrila University of Pula, Faculty of Economics and Tourism “Dr. Mijo Mirkovic”, PhD Candidate, Pula, Croatia Abstract Labour productivity is one of the key measures of economic performance. It represents the total volume of output produced per unit of labour. This paper examines the influence of business investments in research and development and education on labour productivity using system dynamics modelling. The results reveal that investments in edu- cation and training activities generate higher labour productivity growth. The impact of innovations largely depends on their diffusion and adoption that require educated and trained users. The new industrial era makes learning by doing quietly disappear and demand a great flexibility of workers and their ability to rapidly acquire new and master the existing knowledge. Keywords: Labour productivity, Innovation, Research and development, Education, System dynamics modelling JEL classification: J24, O30, O52 Introduction I n macroeconomics, labour productivity is one ofthe most used indicators for dynamic measuring of economic growth, competitiveness and living stan- dard within an economy. Labour productivity is a value that each employedperson creates per his or her input. It measures the amount of real gross domestic product (GDP) produced by an hour of labour or by a person during a given reference period. Labour pro- ductivity provides general information about the ef- ficiency and quality of human capital in the production process for a given economic and social context (International Labour Organization, 2019). The most important determinants of labour pro- ductivity are physical and human capital and tech- nological change. Physical capital implies the tools, equipment and facilities available to workers to produce goods and services. Human capital repre- sents the accumulated knowledge, skills and expertise that workers possess. Technological change implies a combination of invention (ad- vances in knowledge) and innovation (putting the advancement into a new product or service). If labour productivity is growing, it can usually be attributed to the growth in one of these de- terminants. However, if the real gross domestic product is increasing while labour hours remain static, it signals that the labour force has become more productive. Such situations could be observed during economic recessions as workers increase their labour effort to avoid losing their jobs. After the World War II, between 1950 and 1995, labour productivity throughout Europe grew faster than in the USA (by 3.1% in France, Germany, Belgium, Italy and the Netherlands, while by 2.1% in the USA). The trend reversed later on, as labour productivity in Europe slowed down, while the pro- ductivity in the USA rose and even with slowdowns always remained higher than in Europe. Labour productivity growth in the USA averaged 1.1% from 2007 to 2017, while in the EU-15 only 0.6% in the same period, widening the already existing productivity gap. According to the Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF), this effect is largely attributable to Europe's failure to invest in informa- tion and communication technologies which drives labour productivity (Atkinson, 2018). Received 30 November 2020; accepted 8 September 2021. Available online 17 March 2022. E-mail address: ruzica.buksa@gmail.com https://doi.org/10.15458/2335-4216.1297 2335-4216/© 2022 School of Economics and Business University of Ljubljana. This is an open access article under the CC-BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons. org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/). The concept of “learning by doing” is based on learning from experiences resulting from one's own actions (Reese, 2011). Learning takes place through the attempt to solve a problem and it only takes place during activity (Arrow, 1962). The role of experience in increasing productivity has not gone unobserved by scientists. In his work published in 1936, Wright analysed and concluded that the number of labour hours expended in the production of an airframe is a decreasing function of the total number of airframes of the same type previously produced. Furthermore, Lundberg introduced the “Horndal effect” in 1961 that indicates the process of gradual increase in output despite the lack of in- vestments. Lundberg observed that productivity at the Horndal steel works in Sweden increased on average close to 2% per year for a period of 15 years, despite the lack of significant capital investments (Hendel & Spiegel, 2013). In his work on the theme of “learning by doing”, a Nobel prize winner in economic sciences Kenneth Arrow argued that the sustained productivity growth at Horndal could only be attributed to learning from experience (Arrow, 1962). Arrow provided foundational work in endogenous growth theory which holds that in- vestments in human capital, knowledge and inno- vation are significant contributors to economic growth. Early researches of the concept of “learning by doing” have mostly been performed in the manufacturing sector and through a progress function determining variation in production costs over the years (Hirsch, 1952; Montgomery, 1943; Wright, 1936). In further studies (Bahk & Gort, 1993; Rapping, 1965; Sheshinski, 1967), learning by doing has been acknowledged as a productivity enhancing factor in the production function. However, learning is not continuous in the production process; it can be depreciated or interrupted. When a technological change occurs in the production, past knowledge and experience can become irrelevant. Knowledge and skills passed to workers can be lost when they leave the job. Therefore, recent studies try to investigate the effects of learning by doing and labour turnover on productivity (Baffoe-Bonnie, 2016; Chiang, 2004; Da Rocha, Pero, & Corseuil, 2019). This paper contributes to the existing literature in several ways. First, existing studies on labour pro- ductivity and innovation relationship, as well as on labour productivity and investments in human capital have largely focused on production function estima- tion. The purpose of this paper is to challenge and advance these studies by using system dynamics modelling. System dynamics modelling is based on system thinking and enables viewing problems and human actions as interconnected wholes, taking into account also lagged feedback loops that is difficult to do through traditionally used production functions. It enables understanding the big picture around the problem and predicting its long-term change. A sys- tems approach enables to identify where to focus ac- tions and with what intensity to reach the best desirable results. System dynamics modelling has been widely applied to better understand complex system issues from organisational change to urban and world dynamics, including climate change (Lane & Sterman, 2011; Sterman et al., 2013). This paper presents a dynamicmodel thatmay beused to analyse the influence of investments in education and research and development (R&D) on labour produc- tivity and can easily be applied by companymanagers and decisionmakers for long-term strategic planning. What often prevents companies from achieving higher performance is not a lack of resources, knowledge or commitment to change, but a lack of meaningful system thinking capability (Sterman, 2002). Therefore, this paper could also serve to stu- dents to better understand system dynamics model- ling and its application. Second, the model also takes into consideration labour turnover and thus contrib- utes to the recent studies on learning by doing, labour turnover and productivity relationship. Third, a better understanding of the effects of the above relationswill make policymakers, managers and company owners aware of the importance of investing in continuous education and innovation and allow them to adjust their mechanisms, improve their employment de- cisions, provide support and work on key issues that contribute to labour productivity growth. By increasing labour productivity, they will directly contribute to the growth of income per capita and living standard in their countries. The paper is composed of five chapters. After the introduction, the first chapter gives a brief overview of the relevant literature. The second chapter presents the developed model. The results and discussion are presented in the third chapter. The last chapter sum- marizes the most important implications. 1 Theoretical background Labour productivity is directly linked to economic growth, as the latter most frequently occurs when labour productivity increases. With growth in la- bour productivity, an economy is able to produce more goods and services for the same amount of work. The additional production enables higher consumption of these goods and services. Labour productivity is important for everyone in an economy: businesses, workers and government. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 53 Increased labour productivity brings businesses higher profit and thus an opportunity for more in- vestments, while for workers it can translate into higher wages, better working conditions, as well as new job positions. For the government, increased labour productivity results in higher tax revenues. The amount of tax revenue received by the gov- ernment is dependent upon the extent to which productivity grows over a period and paying atten- tion to trends in productivity is therefore vital for policymakers. If productivity grows by less than expected, fiscal deficits could occur, while if it grows by more than expected, there may be fiscal sur- pluses (Sprague, 2014). According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics of the United States Department of Labor, workers in the United States business sector worked the same number of hours in 2013 as they had in 1998 (approximately 194 billion labour hours). During that period, the United States population increased by over 40 million people and thousands of new businesses were established. However, the United States businesses managed to produce 42% ($ 3.5 trillion) more output in 2013 than in 1998 (adjusted for inflation). Such additional output growth must have come from productive sources other than the number of labour hours, i.e. investing in technology, equipment, hiring more high-skilled and experi- enced workers (Sprague, 2014). Drawing on the literature, the conceptual frame- work is composed of two key determinants of labour productivity: innovation, including research and development and education. 1.1 Innovation, research and development and labour productivity Innovation can be defined as the implementation of creative ideas in order to generate value (Baum- gartner, 2009). R&D refers to innovative activities undertaken by companies or governments in developing new or improving existing products or services. R&D is a crucial component of innovation and a key factor in developing new competitive advantages. It directly supports the development of knowledge and technology. Many studies have already been done on inno- vation and labour productivity as well as investment in R&D and labour productivity relationship. Many of them reach the conclusion that innovation and investment in R&D do matter. Crepon, Duguet, and Mairesse (1998) gave one of the most influential contributions in recent literature on economics of innovation. They introduced a structural model that explains productivity by innovation output and innovation output by research investment. By the use of data on innovation output in French manufacturing and econometric methods which correct for selectivity and simultaneity biases, the authors revealed that innovation output rises with research investment and productivity correlates positively with a higher innovation output. L€o€of and Heshmati (2006) investigated the relationship be- tween innovation and company's performance in the multidimensional sensitivity analysis, showing that the model of Crepon, Duguet and Mairesse can be estimated in a simple framework, applying the instrumental variables approach. Mohnen and Hall (2013) did a brief survey of the empirical literature on innovation and productivity. In spite of the usual positive relationship between innovation and productivity, in the EUmember states high costs of innovation often lead to lower com- panies’ productivity. Moreover, in Central and Eastern European countries, a negative feedback ef- fect from productivity to innovation output has been noticed which could indicate that companies rather improve production of existing products than intro- duce new products to the market (Hashi & Stojcic, 2013). Crespi and Zuniga (2012) have examined the determinants of technological innovation and its impact on labour productivity across six Latin Amer- ican countries (Argentina, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Panama and Uruguay). They found out that companies that invest in knowledge are abler to introduce new technological advances and that those that innovate have greater labour productivity. There are two types of innovation output: product and process innovations. Product innovation is the main driver of labour productivity and the influence of process innovation is rather insignificant (Bau- mann & Kritikos, 2016; Mairesse & Robin, 2009). However, process innovations are important, as they improve the transformation process (Kemp et al., 2003; Klomp & Van Leeuwen, 2001). Some companies perform both, product and process in- novations, especially in manufacturing. Stojcic and Hashi (2014) investigated the influence of product, process and both product and process innovations on productivity across several East and West Euro- pean countries. The results revealed that there is a positive and statistically significant relationship be- tween process innovations, as well as product and process innovations together, and productivity. Companies tend to be more successful in product innovation if they use customers as a source of in- formation and in process innovation if they use in- formation from suppliers (Griffith et al., 2006). The econometric results obtained so far indicate the existence of a positive and significant 54 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 relationship between R&D and company and labour productivity growth (Solomon et al., 2015; Tsai & Wang, 2004; Wakelin, 2011). Both applied and experimental R&D, as well as R&D from private sources tend to have higher productivity impacts compared to the basic R&D and publicly funded R&D (Coccia, 2011; Solomon et al., 2015). Although many studies have shown positive correlation be- tween investment in R&D and labour productivity, Benavente (2006) analysed the impact of spending on R&D and innovation on labour productivity using data from Chilean companies. He found out that in the short term, productivity is not affected by innovation or by spending on R&D. The explanation for such results he found in the fact that there were no lags between the implementation of innovations and impact on productivity. Similar results were obtained in the study of Erdil, Cilasun, and Eruygur (2013) in which the contribution of R&D expendi- tures to labour productivity in 22 OECD countries was analysed. The results showed that the initial impact of the growth in the ratio of total R&D expenditure to GDP on labour productivity is negative and insignificant. However, that situation ceases to exist after a period of time and labour productivity starts to rise. In this respect, the pol- icies that favour R&D could help to increase the productivity. 1.2 Education and labour productivity Human capital is a very important contributor to the productivity growth (Engelbrecht, 1997; Pietrzak & Balcerzak, 2016). Rapid technological change makes many skills obsolete quite quickly, while constantly creating demand for new ones. Even though the willingness to participate in adult learning increases with the worker's socio-economic status and the given level of education (Desjardins, 2015), workers usually struggle to improve their knowledge and skills, especially because of their age, lack of time, will and finance resources. In order to improve their ability to absorb new technologies coming out of R&D and keep pace with the competition, companies often invest in education and training of their workers. The U.S. National Center on the Educational Quality of the Workforce (EQW) studied the rela- tionship between education and productivity at more than 3100 U.S. workplaces. In a report pub- lished in 1995, it showed that, on average, a 10% increase in workforce education level led to an 8.6% gain in total factor productivity, while a 10% rise in physical capital (equipment) increased productivity by just 3.4%. Therefore, the marginal value of investing in human capital is almost three times greater than the value of investing in machinery (Stewart, 2010). Further studies (Almeida & Car- neiro, 2009; Galor & Moav, 2004; Stauvermann & Kumar, 2018) confirmed the importance of investing in human capital. However, according to Duran and Rillaers (2002), investing less in education does not necessarily lead to less growth, as the accumulation of physical and human capital displays some degree of substitutability. Some recent studies (Afrooz et al., 2010; Benos & Karagiannis, 2016; Maciulyte-Sniukiene & Matuze- viciute, 2018; Tabari & Reza, 2012) have shown that human capital in terms of education has a positive impact on labour productivity growth. Human capital is composed of general and company-spe- cific knowledge. General knowledge is acquired during schooling, while company-specific knowl- edge is acquired through worker's on-the-job experience, training or through specialised courses. High rate of turnover (loss of experienced workers) has negative effects on learning and labour pro- ductivity (Chiang, 2004; Da Rocha, Pero, & Corseuil, 2019). With the high turnover, companies lose company-specific human capital and it becomes harder to convert “doing” into “learning”. General human capital is easy to compensate by employing new workers, but only by retaining experienced workers can companies convert their “doing” into “learning” (Chiang, 2004). Bartel (1995) studied the relationship between on- the-job training and worker productivity and found that training has a positive and significant effect on job performance, thereby confirming the relation- ship between training and productivity. It is partic- ularly important that companies increase their investments in on-the-job training and learning by doing of workers with secondary school diploma (Yunus, Said, & Hook, 2014). The skills acquired through training should be applicable across all possible departments in the organization to engage the workplace and increase productivity. Although most of the countries have increased efforts in adult learning, the share of adults who participated in education programs and courses for certain European countries was in the range be- tween 24.2% (Italy) and 66.7% (Denmark) in 2012. The Nordic countries, more precisely, Denmark (66.7%), Sweden (65.9%), Finland (65.4%), Netherlands (64.9%) and Norway (64.7%) registered the highest rates of adult participation in education activities (Desjardins, 2015). Despite their high level of economic development, the Nordic countries have a strong record of public policy that aims to promote adult learning, target various barriers to ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 55 participation and ensure equal opportunity to edu- cation for all. Based on the above mentioned considerations and with the goal to enhance the knowledge on the relation between business expenditure on R&D and labour productivity as well as business expenditure on education and training and labour productivity, a system dynamics method of modelling is applied in the next section. 2 Model System dynamics modelling is a method that fa- cilitates the study and analysis of dynamic feedback systems. By using the system dynamics method of modelling, it is possible to look at the whole system and examine the interaction between various fac- tors, rather than examining each factor as isolated. System dynamics modelling offers a more compre- hensive view of the problem and helps explaining which factors and policies lead towards improved system performance. System dynamics modelling is a highly abstract method of modelling which ignores the fine details of a system and produces a general representation of a complex nonlinear dynamical system (Sterman, 2002; The AnyLogic Company, 2019). Originally developed at the Massachusetts Institute of Tech- nology in the 1950s by Jay Forrester (1958), it has been applied in production management, educa- tion, urban planning, public policy, agriculture, en- ergy policy and other areas. System dynamics models are designed to improve decision making and are mainly used for “what-if” scenarios, policy testing and optimisation. Although the method is challenging and time-consuming, one of its main advantages is its suitability to work as a learning laboratory, since it offers the possibility to gain experience with various systems that is often infeasible or costly in the real world (Groff, 2013; Uriona Maldonado & Grobbelaar, 2017). The central part of system dynamics is system thinking (Sterman, 2002). In system dynamics, the real-world processes are represented in terms of stocks (e.g. people, knowledge, money), flows be- tween these stocks (processes that directly add or subtract from a stock), and information that deter- mine the values of the stocks and flows. Stocks can only change through their flows. System dynamics postulates that dynamic processes in systems run in feedback loops and that the history of systems ac- cumulates in defined variables. The accumulated history influences the future development of a sys- tem (Fang et al., 2018). The process of modelling in system dynamics consists of several phases. It starts with the problem formulation, i.e. identification of a specific problem to be addressed, definition of appropriate time ho- rizon and selection of important variables. In the second phase, it is necessary to identify the stocks, flows and feedback structures that can explain the problematic behaviour. The third phase comprises formulation of a simulation model with stock and flow structure and decision rules. In the fourth phase, it is necessary to test the model for validation and behaviour. The final phase refers to policy formulation and evaluation. It comprises the eval- uation of new decisions and strategies that could be implemented in the real world through “what-if” scenarios (Duggan, 2016; Sterman, 2002). Based on the considerations previously mentioned in the introduction and theoretical background, the following model has been devel- oped using the free online software for modelling and simulation Insight Maker (2019): The presented model shows the relationship of diverse variables, stocks and flows that determine the Fig. 1. Labour productivity simulation model. Source: author's model. 56 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 value of labour productivity. The latter is expressed as labour productivity per hour worked, as it provides a better picture of productivity developments in the economy than labour productivity per person employed (it eliminates differences in the full time/ part time composition of the workforce). In order to determine the value of labour produc- tivity per hour worked, some variables have been taken into consideration based on the literature overview and data availability, such as business expenditure on research and development (BERD), business expenditure on education, adult participa- tion in learning and total number of workers.Worker, skilledworker and value added (company's profit) are stocks, while newworkers, worker leaving, education, skilled worker leaving, income and cost of education andR&Dareflows in thismodel. The cloud represents a stock outside the model boundary. It serves as the acknowledgement that the observed system is con- nected in some way to another system. 3 Results and discussion The goal of the model presented in Fig. 1 is to enable company owners and decision managers to see the impact that various policies and changes may have on labour productivity in the company. The above model has been tested on the German economy, using secondary data from the Eurostat database for the year 2016. The German economy has been chosen, as it is one of the most developed economies in Europe and is often used as a role model for many other European countries. In order to simplify the visualisation and calculations, some basic assumptions for the model are defined: the hypothesized company has 100 unskilled workers, each month the company employs two new un- skilled workers, one newly employed unskilled worker leaves the company each month (e.g. he or she did not fit in the company, did not like the job, etc.) and every two months one skilled worker leaves the company (e.g. for a better paid or more challenging job position in another company, mov- ing to another place for family matters, etc.). Ac- cording to Eurostat data (Eurostat, 2019), in 2016 business expenditure on R&D was at 1.99% of the German GDP, while business expenditure on edu- cation and training was at 7% of the German GDP and adult participation rate in education and training was 56.4% (employed persons). The simu- lation is set for a period of ten years. Fig. 2 shows a simulation of labour productivity for the hypothesized company based on the above mentioned data and model assumptions. The model shows that labour productivity in- creases by over 60% after ten years. It firstly grows rapidly and then slows down as the time passes. Fig. 3 reveals that it starts to slow down after 43 months, i.e. when the number of unskilled and skilled workers meet in the company. After 43 months, there are approximately 122 employed workers left in the company, of which 61 are un- skilled and 61 skilled workers. System dynamics is a useful tool for long-term, strategic modelling and simulation. Figs. 2 and 3 show a simulation of labour productivity, the num- ber of unskilled and skilled workers as well as the number of total workers for a period of 120 months Fig. 2. Simulation of labour productivity for hypothesized company for 120 months. Source: author's simulation. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 57 in a hypothesized German company. Company owners and decision makers are often interested in improving labour productivity. Changes in pro- cesses can be expensive and it is therefore better for decision makers to simulate the effects of new pol- icies before applying them in reality in order to avoid unintended consequences. The presented model can easily be used by com- pany managers to analyse various investment sce- narios in similar real-world companies and serve as a decision support tool for long-term strategic planning. Many companies find themselves in a situation where they do not know whether it is more convenient to increase the investment in R&D or education and training activities of their workers in order to improve labour productivity and company profit. The model presented in this paper could help companies to find the right answer through building “what-if” scenarios. Assuming that the company decides to increase its labour productivity by increasing the expenditure on R&D, e.g. decides to invest two times more (4% instead of 1.99% of the German GDP), labour productivity would not in- crease significantly. Fig. 4 shows that increasing the investment in R&D did not contribute to the significant growth in labour productivity (62.56% vs. 61.96% after ten years). Ac- cording to this simulation model, the investment in R&D does not have significant influence on labour productivity. Such a result differs from themajority of researches done in the past and presented in the literature overview, but is in line with the results ob- tained by Benavente (2006) and Erdil et al. (2013). Adoption of new technologies and introduction of new production processes require time and effort that usually lead to the insignificant labour productivity growth, especially in the short run (Ahn, 1999). In- vestment in R&D does not directly increase workers' knowledge and skills. Highly educated and skilled workers usually already work in R&D, but other workers in the company need time to acquire new knowledge and improve their performance. It is important to invest in workers’ education to teach them how to use new developments (e.g. develop- ment of new software does not increase labour pro- ductivity, if workers do not learn how to use it). In the new era of rapid information exchange, learning by doing has become obsolete, as it is time- consuming. Therefore, companies should improve workers’ knowledge and skills by investing in edu- cation and training activities. Fig. 5 shows a simulation model of labour productivity when the company de- cides to invest in education and training of its workers (in this case, it decides to invest twice asmuch, i.e. 14% instead of 7% of the German GDP). The increase of investment in education and training leads to the growth in labour productivity (67% after ten years). This simulation model proves that there is a positive impact of business investment in education and training on labour productivity and such results are in linewith the researches done in the past. However, by using this simulation model the company can design better operating policies and guide effective changes, e.g. it can plan investments in education and training activities. At the beginning of the investment labour productivity growth is faster, as Fig. 3. Simulation of unskilled workers, skilled workers and total number of workers in the hypothesized company for 120 months. Source: author's simulation. 58 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 workers acquire new knowledge and skills through education and training activities. Therefore, the com- pany can increase its investment in education and training in the first years and decrease it when there will bemore skilledworkers thanunskilledworkers in the company. Fig. 6 reveals that with doubling the investment in education and training, the company will need less time to reach the moment when it has the same number of unskilled and skilled workers (32 months instead of 43). Companies should not only increase their ex- penditures on education and training, but also motivate their workers to participate in such activ- ities. Without participation in education and training activities, workers will need more time to acquire new knowledge and skills. In the case of the hypothesized company presented in this paper, if the adult participation rate in education and training activities was halved (28.2% instead of 56.4% employed persons), it would take the com- pany more than 10 years to equalize the number of unskilled and skilled workers. System dynamics modelling is not an intervention, but rather a useful tool for analysing the structure and Fig. 4. Simulation of labour productivity for the hypothesized company for 120 months when it doubles its expenditure on R&D (4% instead of 1.99% of the German GDP). Source: author's simulation. Fig. 5. Simulation of labour productivity for the hypothesized company for 120 months when it doubles its expenditure on education and training (14% instead of 7% of the German GDP). Source: author's simulation. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 59 behaviour of a complex system with nonlinear links and for designing efficient policies. The model pre- sented in this paper highlights the importance of learning and investing in education and training ac- tivities in order to improve labour productivity. Learning by doing is time-consuming and expensive nowadays, especially in high tech and other industries that require rapid technological changes (Ahn, 1999). Although learning by doing is applied in many com- panies, active research and learning is a dominant driver of technological change (Jamasb, 2006). Adop- tion of new technologies requires time and effort and therefore tends to restrict labour productivity growth temporarily. Innovation and R&D can be seen as a prolonged learning process on experience and prob- lem solving, as learning advances are embodied in new technological developments that could improve labour productivity in the long run (Baffoe-Bonnie, 2016). Learning interacts with technology to improve labour productivity, reduces company's costs of pro- duction and increases profit. Thus, companies should increase the investment in professional training and encourage their workers to actively participate in ed- ucation and training activities in order to keep pace with new developments and to apply new knowledge and skills in their everyday work tasks. By increasing the levels of engagement and creating a favourable working environment, companies will prevent high turnover rates that harm labour productivity and affect their development plans. Companies are less likely tofire trainedworkers, as educationand training costs can be high. In addition, company-specific knowledge acquired through worker training cannot be applicable in other companies and could positively influenceworkerwage and their decision to stay in the same company (Konings & Vanormelingen, 2015). 4 Conclusion Labour productivity is a fundamental factor in determining how fast the economy and the average standard of living grow. Existing studies on labour productivity have largely focused on the production function estimation. This paper advances those studies by presenting a system dynamic model. The use of system dynamics represents an untraditional approach in modelling labour productivity. The main advantage of the presented model is that it enables viewing problems and actions as interconnected wholes and takes into account lagged feedback loops. As such, it can easily be applied by company owners and decision makers in long-term strategic planning and labour productivity improvement. Thepurposeof thispaper is toexamine the influence of investments in R&D and education on labour pro- ductivity using system dynamics modelling. There- fore, thispaper represents a contribution to the studies dealing with these relationships and to the system dynamics application. The existing literature mostly shows the importance of innovation and R&D in raising labour productivity and emphasizes that companies should adopt innovations as quickly as possible. However, this study reveals that business expenditure on education and training aswell as adult participation in such activities have stronger influence on the labour productivity growth. The findings pro- vide further evidence on the importance of absorbing Fig. 6. Simulation of unskilled workers, skilled workers and total number of workers in the hypothesized company for 120 months when it invests two times more in education and training (14% instead of 7% of the German GDP). Source: author's simulation. 60 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 new knowledge generated by R&D. The impact of innovations on the labour productivity growth de- pends largely on their diffusion and adoption which can mostly be done by education and training activities. In the era of Industry 4.0, the flexibility of workers and their ability to acquire new knowledge have become the most desirable characteristics. Large and rapid flow of every day information requires constant updating in order to keep pace with the competition. New technologies have become more complex and require specific training for their users. Hence, learning by doing is not sufficient anymore, as it is time consuming. According to this study, adult participation in edu- cation and training activities has become one of the maindrivers that boost labourproductivity. Education should be universally available, as the higher the average level of education in an economy, the higher the accumulated human capital and the higher the labour productivity. It is important that companies and policymakers encourage and support adult participation in education and training activities, because low productivity growth is correlated not just with low wages and low competitiveness but also low government revenues. Reduced government reve- nues, among other things, have as a consequence fewer funds for productivity enhancing expenditures in the areas such as innovation, R&D, education, and therefore decrease labour productivity and living standard over time. Policy interventions can include supporting educational institutions, creating and supporting training programs, supporting specialised online portals for teaching, etc. The presented model can easily be adjusted to each company and extended by adding variables, stocks and flows to analyse additional problems and actions. However, there is no model that will perfectly represent the reality and some limitations should be taken into consideration. Labour turnover is not always easy to predict and it affects produc- tivity. Workers that leave or join the company will differently affect productivity, depending on their level of education and performance. The simulation model developed in this study is limited to just one country and uses the average data for one year. Further research on a larger sample using bigger datasets should be done in the future to confirm the obtained results. The data regarding business expenditures on R&D and edu- cation and training are aggregated data for com- panies of all sizes. Thus, it would be interesting to see in further studies, whether the same results would be achieved in case that the developed model used data only for micro or large companies. References Afrooz, A., Rahim, K. B. A., Noor, Z. B. M., & Chin, L. (2010). Human capital and labor productivity in food industries of Iran. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 2(4), 47e51. https://doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v2n4p47 Ahn, S. (1999). Technology upgrading with learning cost: A solution for two productivity puzzles. OECD Economics Department Work- ing Paper No. 220. https://ssrn.com/abstract=193173 Almeida, R., & Carneiro, P. (2009). The return to firm investments in human capital. Labour Economics, 16(1), 97e106. https:// doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2008.06.002 Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. The Review of Economic Studies, 29(3), 155e173. https:// doi.org/10.2307/2295952 Atkinson, R. D. (2018). How ICT can restore lagging European pro- ductivity growth. Washington DC: Information Technology & Innovation Foundation. https://ssrn.com/abstract¼3324656 Baffoe-Bonnie, J. (2016). Productivity growth and input demand: The effect of learning by doing in a gold mining firm in a developing economy. International Economic Journal, 30(4), 550e570. https://doi.org/10.1080/10168737.2016.1204341 Bahk, B.-H., & Gort, M. (1993). Decomposing learning by doing in new plants. Journal of Political Economy, 101(4), 561e583. https://doi.org/10.1086/261888 Bartel, A. P. (1995). Training, wage growth and job performance: Evidence from a company database. Journal of Labor Economics, 13(3), 401e425. https://doi.org/10.1086/298380 Baumann, J., & Kritikos, A. S. (2016). The link between R&D, innovation and productivity: Are micro firms different? Research Policy, 45(6), 1263e1274. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.respol.2016.03.008 Baumgartner, J. P. (2009). The corporate innovation machine. https:// www.creativejeffrey.com/creative/innovationMachine.pdf Benavente, J. M. (2006). The role of research and innovation in promoting productivity in Chile. Economics Of Innovation And New Technology, 15(4e5), 301e315. https://doi.org/10.1080/ 10438590500512794 Benos, N., & Karagiannis, S. (2016). Do education quality and spillovers matter? Evidence on human capital and productiv- ity in Greece. Economic Modelling, 54, 563e573. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.01.015 Chiang, H. (2004). Learning by doing, worker turnover and produc- tivity dynamics. Econometric Society 2004 Far Eastern Meetings 593. https://ideas.repec.org/p/ecm/feam04/593.html Coccia, M. (2011). The interaction between public and private R&D expenditure and national productivity. Prometheus, 29(2), 121e130. https://doi.org/10.1080/08109028.2011.601079 Crepon, B., Duguet, E., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Research, innovation and productivity: An econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 7(2), 115e158. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599800000031 Crespi, G., & Zuniga, P. (2012). Innovation and productivity: Ev- idence from six Latin American countries. World Development, 40(2), 273e290. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.07.010 Da Rocha, L. P., Pero, V. L., & Corseuil, C. H. (2019). Turnover, learning by doing, and the dynamics of productivity in Brazil. EconomiA, 20(3), 191e210. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econ. 2019.11.001 Desjardins, R. (2015). Participation in adult education opportu- nities: Evidence from PIAAC and policy trends in selected countries. Background paper for the Education for All Global Monitoring Report. https://unesdoc.unesco.org/ark:/48223/pf00 00232396 Duggan, J. (2016). An introduction to system dynamics. In System dynamics modeling with R, lecture notes in social networks (pp. 1e24). Springer International Publishing. https://doi.org/ 10.1007/978-3-319-34043-2_1 Duran, J., & Rillaers, A. (2002). Physical and human capital invest- ment: Relative substitutes in the endogenous growth process. Insti- tuto Valenciano de Investigaciones Economicas, S.A., Working papers, serie AD 2002-18. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 61 Engelbrecht, H.-J. (1997). International R&D spillovers, human capital and productivity in OECD economies: An empirical investigation. European Economic Review, 41(8), 1479e1488. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(96)00046-3 Erdil, E., Cilasun, S. M., & Eruygur, A. (2013). Do R&D expendi- tures matter for labor productivity in OECD countries? An unresolved question. Hacettepe University Journal of Economics and Administrative Sciences, 31(1), 71e82. https://doi.org/ 10.17065/huniibf.103656 Eurostat. (2019). Eurostat database. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/ data/database Fang, Y., Lim, K. H., Qian, Y., & Feng, B. (2018). System dynamics modeling for information systems research: Theory development and practical application. MIS Quarterly, 42(4), 1303e1329. Forrester, J. W. (1958). Industrial dynamics: A major breakthrough for decision makers. Harvard Business Review, 36(4), 37e66. Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2004). From physical to human capital accumulation: Inequality and the process of development. The Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1001e1026. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/0034-6527.00312 Griffith, R., Huergo, E., Mairesse, J., & Peters, B. (2006). Innova- tion and productivity across four European countries. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(4), 483e498. Groff, J. S. (2013). Dynamic systemsmodeling in educational system design& policy. Journal ofNewApproaches in EducationalResearch, 2(2), 72e81. https://doi.org/10.7821/naer.2.2.72-81 Hashi, I., & Stojcic, N. (2013). The impact of innovation activities on firm performance using a multi-stage model: Evidence from the Community Innovation Survey 4. Research Policy, 42(2), 353e366. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.09.011 Hendel, I., & Spiegel, Y. (2013). Small steps for workers, a giant leap for productivity. CSIO Working Paper, No. 0117. Hirsch, W. Z. (1952). Manufacturing progress functions. The Re- view of Economics and Statistics, 34(2), 143e155. https://doi.org/ 10.2307/1928465 International Labour Organization. (2019). Statistics on labour productivity. https://ilostat.ilo.org/topics/labour-productivity/ Jamasb, T. (2006). Technical change theory and learning curves: Patterns of progress in energy technologies. Energy Journal, 28, 1e24. https://doi.org/10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol28-No3-4 Kemp, R. G.M., Folkeringa, M., de Jong, J. P. J., &Wubben, E. F. M. (2003). Innovation and firm performance. (Scales; No. H 200207). EIM. Klomp, L., & Van Leeuwen, G. (2001). Linking innovation and firm performance: A new approach. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8(3), 343e364. https://doi.org/10.1080/ 13571510110079612 Konings, J., & Vanormelingen, S. (2015). The impact of training on productivity and wages: Firm-level evidence. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(2), 485e497. https://doi.org/10.1162/ REST_a_00460 Lane, D. C., & Sterman, J. D. (2011). Jay Wright Forrester. In A. A. Assad, & S. I. Gass (Eds.), Profiles in operations research: Pioneers and innovators (pp. 363e386). Springer. https://doi.org/ 10.1007/978-1-4419-6281-2_20 L€o€of, H., & Heshmati, A. (2006). On the relationship between innovation and performance: A sensitivity analysis. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15(4/5), 317e344. https:// doi.org/10.1080/10438590500512810 Maciulyte-Sniukiene, A., & Matuzeviciute, K. (2018). Impact of human capital development on productivity growth in EU member states. Business, Management and Education, 16(1), 1e12. https://doi.org/10.3846/bme.2018.66 Mairesse, J., & Robin, S. (2009). Innovation and productivity: A firm- level analysis for French manufacturing and services using CIS3 and CIS4 data (1998e2000 and 2002e2004). CREST-ENSAE. Insight Maker. (2019). Start building insights and models for free. https://insightmaker.com Mohnen, P., & Hall, B. H. (2013). Innovation and productivity: An update. Eurasian Business Review, 3(1), 47e65. Montgomery, F. J. (1943). Increased productivity in the construction of liberty vessels. Monthly Labor Review, 57(5), 861e864. Pietrzak, M. B., & Balcerzak, A. P. (2016). Quality of human capital and total factor productivity in new EU member states. In T. Loster, & T. Pavelka (Eds.), Conference proceedings of the 10th international days of Statistics and economics (pp. 1492e1501). Libuse Macakova, Melandrium https://msed.vse.cz/msed_ 2016/sbornik/toc.html Rapping, L. (1965). Learning and world war II production func- tions. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1), 81e86. https://doi.org/10.2307/1924126 Reese, H. W. (2011). The learning-by-doing principle. Behavioral Development Bulletin, 17(1), 1e19. https://doi.org/10.1037/ h0100597 Sheshinski, E. (1967). Tests of the “learning by doing hypothesis”. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 49(4), 568e578. https:// doi.org/10.2307/1928342 Solomon, E., Ugur, M., Guidi, F., & Trushin, E. (2015). Variations in the effect of R&D investment on firm productivity: UK ev- idence. Greenwich Papers in Political Economy, 14081, 1e25. Sprague, S. (2014). What can labor productivity tell us about the U. S. economy? Beyond the Numbers: Productivity, 3(12), 1e9. https://www.bls.gov/opub/btn/volume-3/what-can-labor- productivity-tell-us-about-the-us-economy.htm Stauvermann, P. J., & Kumar, R. R. (2018). Adult learning, eco- nomic growth and the distribution of income. Economies, 6(1). https://doi.org/10.3390/economies6010011 Sterman, J. D. (2002). Business dynamics: System thinking and modeling for a complex world. Working paper series ESD-WP- 2003-01.03. Massachusetts Institute of Technology. https:// dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/102741 Sterman, J. D., Fiddaman, T., Franck, T., Jones, A., McCauley, S., Rice, P., Sawin, E., & Siegel, L. (2013). Management flight simulators to support climate negotiations. Environmental Modelling & Software, 44, 122e135. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.envsoft.2012.06.004 Stewart, T. A. (2010). Intellectual Capital: The new wealth of orga- nization. Crown Publishing Group. Stojcic, N., & Hashi, I. (2014). Firm productivity and type of innovation: Evidence from the community innovation survey 6. Croation Economic Survey, 16(2), 121e146. https://doi.org/ 10.15179/ces.16.2.5 Tabari, N. A. Y., & Reza, M. (2012). Technology and education effects on labour productivity in the agricultural sector in Iran. European Journal of Experimental Biology, 2(4), 1265e1272. The AnyLogic Company. (2019).What is system dynamics modeling? https://www.anylogic.com/use-of-simulation/system- dynamics/ Tsai, K. H., & Wang, J. C. (2004). R&D productivity and the spillover effects of high-tech industry on the traditional manufacturing sector: The case of Taiwan. The World Economy, 27(10), 1555e1570. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2004. 00666.x Uriona Maldonado, M., & Grobbelaar, S. S. (2017). System dy- namics modelling in the innovation systems literature [Paper pre- sentation]. 15th Globelics International Conference, Athens, Greece. Wakelin, K. (2011). Productivity growth and R&D expenditure in UK manufacturing firms. Research Policy, 30(7), 1079e1090. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00136-0 Wright, T. P. (1936). Factors affecting the cost of airplanes. Journal of the Aeronautical Sciences, 3, 122e128. https://doi.org/10.2514/ 8.155 Yunus, N. M., Said, R., & Hook, L. S. (2014). Do cost of training, education level and R&D investment matter towards influ- encing labour productivity? Jurnal Ekonomi Malaysia, 48(1), 133e142. 62 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 Appendix: Model equation list Simulation settings  Time Start: 0  Time Length: 120  Time Step: 1  Time Units: Months Model variables Adult participation in learning  Value: 0.564 BERD  Value: 0.0199 Business exp. on education  Value: 0.07 Labour productivity  Value: ([Worker]þ1.84*[Skilled worker])/([Worker]þ[Skilled worker])þ0.3*[BERD] Total workers  Value: [Skilled worker]þ[Worker] Model stocks Skilled worker  Initial Value: 0 Value added  Initial Value: 100 Worker  Initial Value: 100 Model flows Cost of education and R&D  Rate: [Value added]*([Business exp. on education]þ[BERD])  Alpha: Value added  Omega: None  Positive Only: Yes Education  Rate: 0.4/12*[Adult participation in learning]*[Worker]þ10*[Business exp. on education]*([Adult participation in learning]* [Worker]/18þ(1-[Adult participation in learning]* [Worker])/24)  Alpha: Worker  Omega: Skilled worker  Positive Only: Yes Income  Rate: [Labour productivity]* 100-[Value added]  Alpha: None  Omega: Value added  Positive Only: Yes New workers  Rate: 2  Alpha: None  Omega: Worker  Positive Only: Yes Skilled worker leaving  Rate: 0.5  Alpha: Skilled worker  Omega: None  Positive Only: Yes Worker leaving  Rate: 1  Alpha: Worker  Omega: None  Positive Only: Yes ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:52e63 63