Volume 24 Issue 3 Thematic Issue: The Characteristics and Role of Intangible Capital in Central-Eastern Europe, the Balkans and in the Mediterranean Article 3 September 2022 Intangibles and Participation in Global Value Chains in the EU: Intangibles and Participation in Global Value Chains in the EU: Evidence from the GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles Evidence from the GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles Database Database Petros Dimas National Technical University of Athens, Laboratory of Industrial & Energy Economics, Athens, Greece, petrdimas@chemeng.ntua.gr Dimitrios Stamopoulos National Technical University of Athens, Laboratory of Industrial & Energy Economics, Athens, Greece Aggelos Tsakanikas National Technical University of Athens, Laboratory of Industrial & Energy Economics, Athens, Greece Follow this and additional works at: https://www.ebrjournal.net/home Part of the Growth and Development Commons, and the International Economics Commons Recommended Citation Recommended Citation Dimas, P ., Stamopoulos, D., & Tsakanikas, A. (2022). Intangibles and Participation in Global Value Chains in the EU: Evidence from the GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles Database. Economic and Business Review, 24(3), 152-160. https://doi.org/10.15458/2335-4216.1303 This Original Article is brought to you for free and open access by Economic and Business Review. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economic and Business Review by an authorized editor of Economic and Business Review. ORIGINAL ARTICLE Intangibles and Participation in Global Value Chains in the EU: Evidence from the GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles Database Petros Dimas*, Dimitrios Stamopoulos, Aggelos Tsakanikas National Technical University of Athens, Laboratory of Industrial & Energy Economics, Athens, Greece Abstract The scope of this paper is to provide empirical evidence regarding intangible inputs, global value chains (GVCs) participationandtheirlinkagewithexportsintheEUandtheUK,utilizingdatafromWIODandthenewlyconstructed GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles Database for the period 2000e2014. GVC participation metrics are calculated based on a production-based decomposition framework and include backward and forward participation indices. Intangible inputs follow a breakdown by origin into domestic and imported intangible inputs. Our empirical results suggest that GVC participation (both backward and forward) is a significant driver for exports and highlight the importance of intangibles’ origin in the exporting activities of the EU economies, especially in the case of the non-Euro Area economies. Keywords: Global value chains, Input-Output analysis, Intangible capital, Exports, Competitiveness JEL classification: F14, O30, O52 Introduction and theoretical background G lobal Value Chains (GVCs) have been placed in the epicentre of economic research as the global economy is rapidly moving towards regional and international production and trading clusters where countries no longer act as individual trade partners but rather embed themselves in supply networks that function as a unified entity in inter- national markets. The European Union (EU) can be consideredasapredominantexampleofthistypeof cluster, with EU members constantly trading with each other and forming the concept of ‘the most regionalized region in the world’ (Daudin et al., 2011). Accordingly, EU is no stranger to GVCs as well, with Amador et al. (2015) stating that the EU's GVC participation is currently overcoming the US and Eastern Asian economies. Benkovskis and Kar- adeloglou (2015) further elaborated on the matter, highlighting its linkages with competitiveness and growth for the EU economies. In the same vein, participation in GVCs is further acknowledged as a driverforgrowthin theglobaleconomyaswell (see global studies by Pahl and Timmer (2019) and Constantinescu et al. (2019)). Another point of interest in recent literature streams is the role of intangible assets in the pro- ductivity puzzle. Intangibles-related research faces two main issues that have yet to find a univocal answer in academia, which involve i) the definition of intangible assets, and ii) their quantification. Corrado et al. (2009) provided the first formal defi- nition, according to which intangibles can be grouped into three major categories: a) computer- ized information (including computer software and related activities), b) innovative property (including research and development output, entertainment, design, and intellectual property), and c) economic competencies (branding, marketing, training, and organizational capital). According to their nature, Received 15 March 2021; accepted 25 January 2022. Available online 15 September 2022 * Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: petrdimas@chemeng.ntua.gr (P. Dimas), dstamopoulos@mail.ntua.gr (D. Stamopoulos), atsaka@central.ntua.gr (A. Tsakanikas). https://doi.org/10.15458/2335-4216.1303 2335-4216/© 2022 School of Economics and Business University of Ljubljana. This is an open access article under the CC-BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons. org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/). intangibles are pivotal in the production and diffu- sion of innovation and an alternative characteriza- tion for them is knowledge-based capital (Jona- Lasinio et al., 2019). This definition provided a solid theoretical foundation for empirical efforts towards the quantification of intangibles and the construc- tion of relevant empirical databases. The common baseline among these efforts is the treatment of in- tangibles as capital approximations and thus the quantification procedures included the estimation of capital formation from dedicated expenditure data and specific components of fixed capital (see for example INTAN-Invest by Corrado et al., 2018; INNODRIVEbyPiekkola,2011)andthemostrecent release of the EU-KLEMS database (Stehrer et al., 2019). These databases provided the empirical data to support several investigations regarding the ef- fect of intangibles to growth, with Roth and Thum (2013), Niebel et al. (2017) and Piekkola (2018) providing evidence of strong and positive relation- ship between intangible capital and productivity growth. Intangibles are also connected with partic- ipation in GVCs, as intangible intensive activities appear to accumulate maximum shares in VA appropriation along the production chain (OECD, 2013). In support of this claim, Jona-Lasinio et al. (2019) provided evidence of the importance of intangible capital as a driver for GVC participation. As the main body of intangibles-related literature focusesontheircontributiontoproductivitygrowth, anothermainaspectregardingthescopeandnature of intangibles is still absent from relevant research, namely the origin dimension of intangible assets. The recently developed GLOBALINTO Input- Output Intangibles Database-GIOID (Dimas et al., 2022) provides the proper framework and empirical tools to explore this dimension, as it sheds light to some missing dimensions that previous approaches failedtoaddress,suchaswheretheintangibleassets come from and who produces them. Under this framework, the database investigates the origin dimension regarding intangibles in the EU, intro- ducing a novel approach based on inter-industry trade of utilities and the treatment of intangibles as intermediate inputs/producer's services. The novel intangibles metrics are compatible with the tradi- tional and advanced GVC participation indices and can be co-integrated in studies that focus on GVC trade in the EU and the investigation of the com- bined effect of intangibles (domestic and imported) and GVC participation (in all its aspects) to growth and competitiveness via traditional growth ac- counting exercises and novel empirical approaches. This paper is embedded in the latter framework and aims to provide quantitative insights regarding GVC participation and intangible assets in the EU- 27 plus the United Kingdom, 1 and empirically investigate their relationship and effects in competitiveness for the EU members. Our main research hypothesis indicates that both intangible assets and GVC participation are major de- terminants that drive the exporting performance of the EU economies. We empirically investigate this hypothesis through the calculation of the produc- tion-based GVC indicators following the innovative framework provided by Wang et al. (2017) and uti- lizing data at the country level from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD) (Timmer et al., 2015) and the newly constructed GIOID (Dimas et al., 2022; Tsakanikas et al., 2022) for the period 2000e2014. Furthermore, we test the calculated in- dicatorsinsimplepanelregressionsasdeterminants of exports for the EU. In this line, we develop two separate sub-samples, distinguishing between Euro Area (EA) and non-Euro Area economies, and further introduce different intangible factors in the specifications to investigate different aspects of in- tangibles contribution to exports. The structure of the remainder of this paper is as follows: At the first stage, we provide a description regarding the quantification of GVC participation indicators based on IeO analysis and the produc- tion-based decomposition approach applied in this paper. The second stage of this paper presents a short description of the GIOID, with details regarding the methodological approach, the data, and the key novelties that this database presents. The third stage of this paper provides the method- ology and the main indicators utilized in the empirical part of this study and the fourth stage provides descriptive statistics and the regression results. The fifth and final part presents the con- clusions of this study and discusses limitations and future research. 1 Input-Output frameworks of analysis for GVC participation 1.1 Methodological overview regarding Inter- Country Input-Output tables The methodological basis of the present paper originates from Leontief's (1936) IeO framework, 1 For abbreviation purposes, we will refer to EU-27 and the UK as EU-28 in the following sections of this paper. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 153 which has since been a predominant tool for the quantitative analysis of production in- terdependencies and the modelling of economic systems. IeO models generally treat an economy as a set of interconnected sub-components, each requiring inputs of goods and services from the other components and producing goods and ser- vices that are then consumed by the other compo- nents for production or final use. These interdependencies are depicted in IeO tables and the framework relies on three main assumptions about the nature and structure of the economic system depicted in the table. Namely the system is completely internal (all output is eventually usede consumed),with noeffects ofproductionscaling,and finally, that every industry corresponds to a single product and vice versa (i.e., no substitute products exist). While the IeO tables are usually compiled by statistical institutions at the national level (the eco- nomic system is the economy and the components are the different national industries and final uses) based on its supply and use tables, there exist dif- ferences in currency, accounting practices, trade balances and industry classifications among different countries that often pose difficulties in drawing meaningful comparisons. To overcome such issues, Inter-Country Input-Output Tables (ICIOTs) have been developed, with the most prominent ones being the World Input-Output Database (Timmer et al., 2015) and OECD's Inter- Country Input-Output (ICIO) Tables. Assuming a hypothetical inter-national economy with N countries, with K industries each, an ICIOT follows the structure presented below in Table 1. In Table 1, X is the global matrix of intermediate consumption, with each sub-matrix X i;j being a K K sized block containing the flows of intermediate goods and services from the sectors of country C i to the sectors of country C j for intermediate con- sumption. F i;j is a K D matrix regarding the con- sumptionoftheDfinalusersfromtheproductionof country C i to country C j , VA i is a 1 K vector of the value added per sector of production from country C i , and Y i ;I i are K 1 and 1 K vectors containing thetotal gross output andthetotal requirementsfor inputs per sector and country pair. Following the core assumptions of the framework, total output must equal total input: Y i ¼ I i 0 . The global co- efficients of production can then be estimated 2 as A ¼ XY 0 1 ,resultingina NK NK matrix.Following these formulations, total output of the economy can be written as Y ¼ AI 0 þ F,orasY¼ð I id AÞ 1 I, with ðI id AÞ 1 ¼ L being the familiar Leontief in- verse matrixfor theglobaleconomyand I id an NK NK identity matrix. Since the seminal work of Hummels et al. (2001), the quantification of GVC participation has been based on various metrics that derive from ICIOTs, such as exports of intermediates and various value- added (VA) decomposition approached developed by different research groups at both industry and country levels. The foundations for GVC research were set through the construction of global ICIOTs such as the aforementioned WIOD (Timmer et al., 2015) and OECD's ICIOTs. Koopman et al. (2014) provided a formal framework for the decomposition of gross exports into two major components that defined the GVC empirical research; domestic value added(DVA)and foreign value added(FVA)embodied in gross exports. This framework paved the way for the development of backward (focused on FVA) and forward (focused on DVA) participation indices that wereutilizedwidelyinempiricalgrowthresearchby both academia and economic research institutions (see for example Amador et al., 2015; Benkovskis & Karadeloglou, 2015; Constantinescu et al., 2019; Tsakanikas et al., 2022; World Bank, 2020). Table 1. Input-Output table framework for an international economy of N partner countries with K industries per country. Intermediate Consumption Final Uses Total Output Country C 1 C 2 […] C N C 1 […] C N Intermediates Supply C 1 X 1;1 X 1;2 […] X 1;N F 1;1 […] F 1;N Y 1 C 2 X 2;1 X 2;2 […] X 2;N F 2;1 […] F 2;N […] […][ …][ …][ …][ …][ …][ …][ …][ …] C N X N;1 X N;2 […] X N;N F N;1 […] F N;N Y N Value Added VA 1 […][ …] VA N Total Input I 1 I 2 I N 2 In the context of the present study the apostrophe (A 0 ) denotes the transpose matrix of A and the hat accent ( b A) the diagonal matrix of line/column vector A. 154 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 These indicators were exports-driven and calcu- lated based on a country's/sector's gross exports. In this study, we adopt an alternative approach to- wards the quantification of GVC participation, that is production-based and relies on the decomposi- tion of value-added into domestic and foreign components, as introduced by Wang et al. (2017). Our indicators are constructed utilizing available data from WIOD for the period 2000e2014. The detailed procedure towards the construction of the production driven backward and forward GVC participation indices is described in the following section. 1.2 Tracing of value added in inter-country trade following a production-based approach In an ICIOT, the flows of goods and services be- tween the different sectors and countries are immediately identifiable and can be traced along the production chains. However, information about the traded value added that is incorporated in those flows requires further elaboration. The first step is to estimate the share of value added embodied in the total output of each sector and country: VA to ¼VAY 0 1 ð1Þ Multiplying VA to by the global Leontief matrix and the vector of gross final uses per industry and country of origin, the global matrix of value-added traded by partner industryecountry pair can be formed: VA oc; oi; pc; pi tr ¼ d VA to L c F to ð2Þ This matrix can then be further decomposed to form the country-industry network of value-added flows by partner of destination or partner of origin and by type of use (for intermediate or final uses). The present paper follows the decomposition method described by Wang et al. (2017), which uti- lizes the domestic and foreign submatrices of pro- duction coefficients and final demand due to bilateral trade from the ICIOTs to separate VA that is consumed in its country of origin from VA that is exported and then consumed abroad or is further embodied in other partner countries exports: VA oc; oi; pc; pi tr ¼ VA cons d/d þVA cons d/f þVA exp=imp d/f ð3Þ where VA cons d/d is the VA that is consumed in the country in which it firstly originates, VA cons d/f is the VA that is produced, then embodied in the final goods exports of a countryesector pair and then imported and consumed in another countryesector pair, and VA exp=imp d/d is the VA that is embodied in the intermediate exports or imports a countryesector pair. This last form of VA can then be either used in the partner country for production or be further re-exported. Todevelop themeasuresofparticipationinGVCs at the country level, we adopt the net trade concept (Wang et al., 2017) with the necessary modifications to account for the higher aggregations. The share of a country's total VA that consists of domestic VA that originates through downstream activities (‘for- ward’ participation in GVCs) can be written 3 as VA oc GVC; ds ¼ X j¼K j¼1 X i¼N i¼1 VA exp=imp d/f X j¼K j¼1 X i¼N i¼1 VA oc; oi; pc; pi tr ð4Þ while the share of foreign VA imported through intermediates in its final uses (‘backward’ participa- tion in GVCs) is given at the country level by: VA pc GVC; us ¼ X i¼K i¼1 X j¼N j¼1 VA exp=imp d/f X i¼K i¼1 X j¼N j¼1 VA oc; oi; pc; pi tr ð5Þ 2 Intangibles inter-country trade: the GLOBALINTO Input-Output intangibles database Most of the available intangible capital databases provide insightful information regarding invest- ment in intangible capital and a breakdown among different categories of intangible assets in line with Corrado et al. (2009) definition. However, some important questions still remain unanswered, such as Where do these investments go? and Who produces these intangible assets and where do the intangible assets come from? The GLOBALINTO IeO Intangibles Database provides the empirical insights to tackle these gaps in intangibles quantification literature, by treating intangiblesasintermediate inputs in theproduction process of each industry/country. The database provided intangibles-related data for 56 2-digit NACE REV. 2 industries from all EU-27 countries including the UK, for the period 2000e2014. The framework of this novel database is constructed based on theCorradoet al.(2009) approach andkey elements of the INNODRIVE methodology (Piek- kola, 2011), and identifies certain knowledge- 3 (i;jÞ along with ðN;KÞ denote the summation direction (e.g., row wise for all countries first and column wise for all industries second, etc.). ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 155 intensive service sectors in the economy as in- tangibles producing sectors. The treatment of in- tangibles as inputs and more accurately as producer's services enables the quantification of trade-in-intangibles between industries and coun- tries and goes beyond the level of established da- tabases through the introduction of the origin dimension, as the user can distinguish between the intangibles that are produced domestically, and the intangibles purchased from abroad via imports. The database is constructed drawing raw IeO data from the 2016 release of WIOD, which covers the inter-industry trade between 56 2-digit NACE Rev.2economicsectorsfrom43countries(including all EU-28 members) and an estimate for the rest of the world. In the framework of the database, 4 knowledge-intensive services sectors are identified as intangibles producers, namely: J62-J63: Computer programming, consultancy, and related activities; Information service activities. M72: Scientific Research and Development (R&D). M73: Advertising and market research. N sector: Administrative and support service activities. Under this scope, intangibles are quantified as producer services in the inter-industry and inter- country trade, a novel dimension that enables the study of trade-in-intangibles in the international markets and the globalized economy. The method- ological framework regarding the identification of intangibles is embedded in the basic principles of IeO analysis and is centered around the in- tangibles-producing sectors. As a result, this approach can be further expanded into different ICIOTs that provide appropriate data regarding the inter-industry and inter-country trade. The intangibles-related data in GIOID are further consolidated with export and competitiveness sta- tistics calculated from the WIOD and R&D expen- diture data from Eurostat. Furthermore, the database includes information about patent appli- cations to the European Patent Office (EPO) per industry, at the NACE Rev.2 level, which derive from Eurostat. A detailed description regarding the construction and the key elements of GIOID can be found in Dimas et al. (2022) and its conceptual and the methodological underpinnings are thoroughly dis- cussed in Tsakanikas et al. (2022). 3 Empirical methodology and model specifications To empirically assess the contribution of GVC participation and intangibles in the competitiveness of the EU, 4 we formulate two different sub-samples of the EA 5 and non-EA economies, 6 based on the assumption that a common currency enhances traditionaltradeandGVC-tradeactivities.Weselect a relevant export performance indicator from GIOID that is the share of gross exports to total output per country, as a proxy for competitiveness: GX Yc;t ¼ GX c;t Y c;t ð6Þ where GX c;t and Y c;t represent the gross exports and total output of country c at time t respectively. To account for the effect of intangibles, we intro- duce the origin dimension as a key novelty in the intangibles-related studies, utilizing two separate indicators from GIOID, as described in the following equations: dIntan c;t ¼ dom:intangibleinputs c;t I c;t ð7Þ iIntan c;t ¼ imp:intangibleinputs c;t I c;t ð8Þ where dIntan c;t stands for the share of domestically produced intangibles inputs in c at time t to its total intermediate consumption of utilities (I c;t )a n d iIntan c;t stands for the share of imported intangibles inputs. Previous empirical investigations regarding in- tangibles were directed towards exploring the overall effect of investment in intangible capital rather than trying to distinguish between the domestically purchased and imported assets. In order to provide an element of comparison and highlightthekeynoveltiesoftheintangibleinputs’ indicators incorporated in GIOID, we also intro- duced an aggregate intangibles indicator in our specification, which does not account for in- tangibles origin, as described in equation (9): 4 Cyprus, Luxembourg, and Malta are excluded from the study, due to the nature of their economies and their special characteristics regarding inter- national trade and domestic economic activities. 5 Euro Area members include Austria, Belgium, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, and Spain. 6 Non-Euro Area economies include Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Hungary, Poland, Romania, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. 156 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 tIntan c;t ¼ totalintangibleinputs c;t I c;t ð9Þ The GVC participation indices utilized in the empirical analysis are the ‘backward’ and ‘forward’ participation in GVCs as described in detail in the previous section and are depicted in equation (10). gvc b c;t ¼VA pc GVC; us gvc fc;t ¼VA oc GVC; ds ð10Þ We model the aforementioned variables into four separate specifications to study the effects of intangible inputs and GVC participation to exports for the EA and non-EA EU countries in the period 2000e2014. The specifications are presented in the following equations: i: GX Y c;t ¼a o þa 1 gvc b c;t þa 2 gvc f c;t þa 3 tIntan c;t þl t þ3 c;t ii: GX Y c;t ¼b o þb 1 gvc b c;t þb 2 gvc f c;t þb 3 dIntan c;t þb 4 iIntan c;t þl t þ3 c;t iii: GX Y c;t ¼g o þg 1 gvc b c;t þg 2 gvc f c;t þg 3 dIntan c;t þl t þ3 c;t iv: GX Y c;t ¼d o þd 1 gvc b c;t þd 2 gvc f c;t þd 3 iIntan c;t þl t þ3 c;t Our specifications follow a reverse approach. At first, we introduce a model with GVC participa- tion indices and total intangible inputs to account for the effects of GVC participation and intangibles in exports. Subsequently, we distinguish between domestic and imported intangibles to identify to which type (or both) of intangibles the previously identified effect is attributed to. Furthermore, we provide specifications that account for the in- tangiblesorigindimensionseparatelytocorroborate our results. The econometric approach includes simple Fixed Effects (FE) 7 panel regressions to ac- count for the country-specific effects with time dummies to account for unobserved time effects via l t , while e c;t represents the error term. We further turn to Driscoll and Kraay (1998) robust standard errors to account for heteroskedasticity, serial autocorrelation and contemporaneous autocorrela- tion (cross sectional dependence) present in the results. 8 4 Results and discussion The main descriptive statistics regarding the sampleoftheEU-28economiesutilizedinthisstudy is presented in Table 2. Table 3 presents the correlation matrix of the variables included in this study. The backward and forward participation indices of the EU-28 economies at the start (2000) and end (2014) of the study's timeframe are reflected on the following scatterplots in Fig. 1. First, there is a notable upwards shift in the participation intensity for almost all countries, both via downstream and upstream production activities, as can be observed fromtherelativepositionsofthecountriesalongthe (x; y) axis. Even economies that were initially less involved in the backward participation in GVCs (notably Bulgaria, Greece, Portugal) have been increasing their shares of imported inputs used for final production purposes. Second, there has been a gradual and proportional increase in both forward and backwards participation, which is evident by theclusteringoftheobservationsalongthediagonal linein2014comparedto2000.Thispatterndepictsa bidirectional GVC deepening for most of the Euro- pean economies and relates with a positive rela- tionship between forward and backward participation.Thisfindingisfurthercorroboratedby the correlation statistics of Table 3, where forward andbackwardparticipationinGVCsarefoundtobe positively correlated (Pearson stat. value of 0.776). Furthermore, we document apparent clusters of countries with geographical proximity and eco- nomic conditions. For example, the Southern Euro- pean economies (Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy) move closer to each other and settle in the more forward-intensive part of GVC participation, while some central European countries (Hungary, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia) also tend to increase Table 2. Summary descriptive statistics for the variables of the adjusted EU-28 sample for the period 2000e2014. Obs. Mean Standard Dev. Min Max GX_Y 375 0.227 0.085 0.054 0.514 gvc_b 375 0.196 0.059 0.103 0.372 gvc_f 375 0.180 0.059 0.059 0.351 dIntan 375 0.062 0.025 0.018 0.146 iIntan 375 0.016 0.029 0.002 0.218 tIntan 375 0.078 0.039 0.020 0.253 7 Random Effects and Pooled OLS were also tested, and FE were selected based on the results of the Hausman specification test (Hausman, 1978). 8 Heteroskedasticity was detected via the implementation of the modified Wald statistic for group heteroskedasticity (Greene, 2000), serial autocorre- lation was detected via Wooldridge's (2010) test and contemporaneous autocorrelation/cross section dependence via Pesaran's (2007) diagnostic test. ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 157 their participation in GVCs (in this case, both for- ward and backward) and move closer together. Another observation that can be drawn relates to the differences in GVC participation between our two separate sub-groups, the EA (shown in bold font in the graphs) and non-EA economies (rest of the sample of the EU-28). There has been a signifi- cant shift towards backward participation for EA economies, regardless of their generally perceived statuses as either ‘mainly exporting’ or ‘mainly importing’ countries. This showcases the gradual increase of share the foreign VA content of the goods and services that are consumed in final uses, as the EU becomes more strongly interconnected in terms of trade for production purposes and is gradually deepening its bidirectional participation in GVCs. Following the descriptive analysis, the main empirical results of the model specifications are presented in Table 4. Table 3. Correlation matrix for the variables of the adjusted EU-28 sample for the period 2000e2014. GX_Y gvc_b gvc_f dIntan iIntan tIntan GX_Y 1.000 gvc_b 0.665*** 1.000 gvc_f 0.793*** 0.776*** 1.000 dIntan 0.080 0.463*** 0.191*** 1.000 iIntan 0.540*** 0.434*** 0.470*** 0.028 1.000 tIntan 0.357*** 0.019 0.229*** 0.650*** 0.742*** 1.000 Note. Pearson correlation statistics reported. *Significant at 10% level. **Significant at 5% level. ***Significant at 1% level. Fig. 1. Backward and forward participation in GVCs for all EU-28 counties in 2000 and 2014. Note. EA economies are presented in bold font and green markers. Source: Authors' calculations based on WIOD. Table 4. Fixed effects panel regression results with Driscoll and Kraay (1998) robust standard errors. Euro-Area Rest of the EU-28 GX_Y (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) gvc_b 0.37*** 0.33** 0.42** 0.28** 0.36*** 0.29*** 0.36*** 0.28*** (0.09) (0.11) (0.15) (0.10) (0.07) (0.08) (0.08) (0.08) gvc_f 1.12*** 1.13*** 1.14*** 1.15*** 1.03*** 1.04*** 1.03*** 1.04*** (0.09) (0.08) (0.07) (0.08) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) tIntan 0.34*** 0.16 (0.11) (0.12) dIntan 0.25* 0.06 0.07 0.06 (0.13) (0.12) (0.11) (0.12) iIntan 0.37*** 0.30** 1.43** 1.42** (0.12) (0.12) (0.54) (0.53) constant 0.07** 0.06* 0.06 0.03 0.06*** 0.05*** 0.05*** 0.04** (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Time dummies✓✓✓✓✓✓✓✓ Observations 240 240 240 240 135 135 135 135 within R 2 0.79 0.80 0.78 0.79 0.96 0.96 0.95 0.96 No. of groups 16 16 16 16 9999 Note. Driscoll and Kraay (1998) robuststandard errors in parentheses.*Significant at 10% level.**Significant at 5% level.***Significant at 1% level. 158 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 The empirical results indicate that GVC partici- patione both backward and forwarde is vital for theexportingactivitiesoftheEU-28memberswitha positive and statistically significant impact on ex- ports in all specifications and sub-samples. Focusing on intangibles, we observe a positive andstatisticallysignificanteffectonexportsforEA. Delving more into the matter through the break- down of intangibles per origin to domestic and imported,weobserveastrongereffectforthelatter with domestic intangibles being a driver for ex- ports only in the presence of imported intangibles. This finding is even more acute in the case of the rest of the EU-28 members that do not share a common currency. For the non-EA countries, in- tangibles appear to not affect exports in a statisti- cally significant manner. However, when accounting for the intangibles’ origin, we identify thatthe insignificanceoftotal intangiblesis related with the domestic intangibles as the imported share appears to be a statistically significant driver for exports in the respective sub-sample of economies. 5 Conclusions This paper provides insights regarding intangible inputs and GVC participation (backward and for- ward) in the EU utilizing available data from WIOD and the novel GLOBALINTO IeO Intangibles Database for the period 2000e2014. Furthermore, we investigate the effect of GVC participation and intangible inputs in the exporting activities of the EU countries via simple panel regressions in order to highlight different dimensions related with in- tangibles that were previously unexplored in rele- vant literature. In the timeframe of this study (2000e2014), we observedanincrease inboth forwardandbackward participation intensity for almost all countries, with further shifts towards incorporating more foreign value added in their consumption and exports of goods and services, especially for the EA countries. Furthermore, a clustering pattern emerges for economies with relatively comparable production characteristics and overall macroeconomic condi- tions, most notably in the case of the Southern Eu- ropean and most Central European economies. The key empirical findings regarding the contri- butionofintangibleinputsandGVCparticipationin exports are summed below: i. GVC participatione both backward and for- ward e is a driver for the exporting perfor- mance of the EU members. ii. Intangible inputs appear to be a driver for exports for the EA economies. iii. Intangibles' origin does matter for the non-EA economies, as imported intangibles appear to be a significant driver for exports, whereas domestically produced intangibles are not relatedwithexportsinastatisticallysignificant manner. The empirical evidence of this study highlights theimportanceoftheorigindimensioninintangible assets,asimportedintangiblesappeartobeadriver for exports for all EU-28 economies. Especially in the case of the non-EA economies, imported in- tangibles outperform domestic intangibles in terms of contribution to exports. This dimension was previously unexplored in the intangibles-related research and constitutes a key novelty of the GIOID compared to the existing databases. Furthermore, the producer services approach on intangible assets adopted by GIOID provides a framework for the quantification and study of trade-in intangibles be- tween industries and across countries, a dimension that the empirical evidence of this study highlights as a significant factor that defines the exporting ac- tivities of the EU-28 economies. TheresultsofthisstudyareinlinewithTsakanikas etal.(2020)whereintangiblesandGVCparticipation (via a different approximation) appear to be drivers forproductivityperformanceintheEUatthecountry level. Furthermore, the significance of the imported intangible inputs in the EU's competitiveness is also corroboratedinTsakanikasetal.(2022)attheindustry level and with a special focus on manufacturing ac- tivitiesintheEU.Thecollectiveevidencethatderives from research based on GIOID suggests that in- tangibles shouldbe placed in theepicenter of future industrial policy frameworks in the EU, with special focus on trade-in intangibles and the intangible transactions between different EU members. Future policy frameworks should aim to establish and properlysafeguardtheintangiblestradeintheEU,as itappearstobeacrucialbeneficialfactorfortheEU's economiesanditsoverallcompetitiveness. As stated above, the focus of this paper is to explore the relationship among export activity, different types of GVC participation (forward and backward) and intangible assets. However, our approach remains agnostic to the actual ownership of these assets, an inherited shortcoming that stems from the nature of IeO models, which, in multire- gional settingse as in the case of WIODe can only provide information regarding the location of pro- duction. Despite this fact, this novel dataset pro- vides fertile ground for future research that should ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160 159 aim to distinguish among different types of in- tangibles and provide empirical evidence both per origin as well as per type of an intangible asset. We further encourage future endeavors to focus into industry and country-specific case studies and pro- vide novel insights that correspond to regional and national determinants that shape export performance. Acknowledgement This paper draws data from the GLOBALINTO Input-Output Intangibles database, which was developed under the H2020-EU.3.6.1.1. GLOBAL- INTO project (GLOBALINTO: Capturing the value of Intangible Assets in Micro Data to Promote the EU'sGrowthandCompetitiveness,contractnumber 822259). References Amador, J., Cappariello, R., & Stehrer, R. (2015). Global value chains: A view from the euro area. Asian Economic Journal, 29(2), 99e120. https://doi.org/10.1111/asej.12050 Benkovskis, K., & Karadeloglou, P. (2015). Compendium on the diagnostic toolkit for competitiveness. ECB Occasional Paper, no. 163. Constantinescu, C., Mattoo, A., & Ruta, M. (2019). Does vertical specialisationincreaseproductivity? The World Economy, 42(8), 2385e2402. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12801 Corrado, C., Haskel, J., Jona-Lasinio, C., & Iommi, M. (2018). Intangible investment in the EU and US before and since the Great Recession and its contribution to productivity growth. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development, 2(1), 11e36. https://doi.org/10.24294/jipd.v2i1.205 Corrado,C.,Hulten,C.,&Sichel,D.(2009).Intangiblecapitaland U.S. economic growth. Review of Income and Wealth, 55(3), 661e685. Daudin, G., Rifflart, C., & Schweisguth, D. (2011). Who produces for whom in the world economy? Canadian Journal of Eco- nomics/Revue canadienne d'economique, 44(4), 1403e1437. Dimas, P., Stamopoulos, D., Tsakanikas, A., & Vasileiadis, M. (2022). GLOBALINTO input-output intangibles database: In- dustry-level data on intangibles for the EU-27 and the UK. Data in Brief, 107932. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.dib.2022.107932 Driscoll,J.C.,&Kraay,A.C. (1998).Consistent covariancematrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. The Review of Economicsand Statistics, 80(4),549e559.https://doi.org/10.1162/ 003465398557825 Greene, W. (2000). Econometric analysis. Prentice-Hall. Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econ- ometrica, 46(6), 1251e1271. Hummels, D., Ishii, J., & Yi, K.-M. (2001). The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 75e96. Jona-Lasinio, C., Manzocchi, S., & Meliciani, V. (2019). Knowl- edge based capital andvalue creation in global supply chains. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 148(Jul), Article 119709. Koopman, R., Wang, Z., & Wei, S.-J. (2014). Tracing value-added and double counting. The American Economic Review, 104(2), 459e494. Leontief,W.W. (1936). Quantitative input andoutput relationsin the economic systems of the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 18(3), 105. Niebel,T.,O'Mahony,M., &Saam,M. (2017).Thecontribution of intangible assets to sectoral productivity growth in the EU. Review of Income and Wealth, 63(Feb.), S49eS67. https:// doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12248 OECD (2013). Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value Chains. OECD publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/ 9789264189560-en Pahl,S.,&Timmer,M.P.(2019).Patternsofverticalspecialisation in trade: Long-run evidence for 91 countries. Review of World Economics, 155(3), 459e486.https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-019- 00352-3 Pesaran, M. H. (2007). A simple panel unit root test in the pres- ence of cross-section dependence. Journal of Applied Econo- metrics, 22, 265e312. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.951 Piekkola, H. (2011). Intangible capitaldINNODRIVE perspective. InH.Piekkola(Ed.),Intangiblecapital-driverofgrowthinEurope. Vaasa, Finland: Proceedings of the University of Vaasa. Piekkola, H. (2018). Broad-based intangibles as generators of growthin Europe. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 27(4), 377e400. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2017.1376170 Roth, F., & Thum, A. E. (2013). Intangible capital and labor pro- ductivity growth: Panel evidence for the EU from 1998-2005. Review of Income and Wealth, 59(3), 486e508. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/roiw.12009 Stehrer,R.,Bykova,A.,J€ ager,K.,Reiter,O.,&Schwartzhappel,M. (2019). Industry level growth and productivity data with spe- cial focus on intangible assets. In Report on methodologies and data construction for the EU KLEMS release 2019 (Contract No. 2018 ECFIN-116/SI2.784491 Deliverable 3). Vienna: Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (Wiener Institut für Internationale Wirtschaftsvergleiche wiiw). Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R., & de Vries,G.J.(2015).Anillustrateduserguidetotheworldinput- output database: The case of global automotive production. Review of International Economics, 23(3), 575e605. https:// doi.org/10.1111/roie.12178 Tsakanikas, A., Caloghirou, Y., Dimas, P., & Stamopoulos, D. (2022). Intangibles, innovation, and sector specialization in global value chains: A case study on the EU's and the UK's manufacturing industries. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 177, 121488. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.techfore.2022.121488 Tsakanikas, A., Roth, F., Calio, S., Caloghirou, Y., & Dimas, P. (2020). The contribution of intangible inputs and participation in global value chains to productivity performance: Evidence from the EU-28, 2000-2014. Hamburg Discussion Papers in Interna- tional Economics. No.5. Hamburg: University of Hamburg. Wang, Z., Wei, S.-J., Yu, X., & Zhu, K. (2017). Measures of participationinglobalvaluechainsandglobalbusinesscycles. NBER Working Paper Series, No. 23222. National Bureau of Economic Research. Wooldridge, J. M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT press. World Bank. (2020). World development report 2020: Trading for developmentintheageofglobalvaluechains.WorldBankGroup. 160 ECONOMIC AND BUSINESS REVIEW 2022;24:152e160