IMAD Working Paper Series http://www.unnar.qov.si/en/authors contributions Gonzalo Caprirolo and Jože Markič Financial crisis in euro area and policy response Working Paper 1 /2015, Vol. XXIV The contents of the papers may be reproduced In whole or In part provided that the source Is aclcnowledged. Copyright belongs to the authors rather than IMAD, as the opinions, findings and conclusions expressed are entirely those of the authors and do not represent IMAD's official views. Abstract: Six years since the outset of the crisis its nature in the euro area is still hotly debated. Views include fiscal prolificacy, lack of competitiveness, current account imbalances, sudden stop of capital and banking crisis. The paper argues that the crisis in the euro area since the outset has been financial and systemic, taking place on the background of a leveraged private sector financed from the core of the euro area and highly Integrated financial system without integrated risk monitoring. Yet, the crisis has revealed that member states in absence of a lender of last resort function are subject to destabilizing speculation and some have practically narrow or no margin of maneuver to offset shocks requiring the completion of the monetary union with a common fiscal stabilizing mechanism. Key words: euro area, financial crisis, peripheral countries, core countries, balance of payments, sudden stop of capital, banking crisis. Target balance, monetary policy, fiscal policy Publisher: Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development Gregorčičeva 27 SI-1000 Ljubljana Slovenia Phone: (+386) 1 478 1012 Fax: (+386) 1 478 1070 E-mail: gp.umar@gov.si Editor in Chief: Valerija Korošec, PhD (valerija.korosec@gov.si) Working paper: Financial crisis in euro area and policy response Authors: Gonzalo Carlos Caprirolo Cattoretti, MSc (qonzalo.caprirolo(agov.si), Jože Markič, PhD (ioze.markicOgov.si) Not language edited. Peer reviewed. Ljubljana, March 2015 CIP - Kataložni zapis o publikaciji Narodna in univerzitetna knjižnica, Ljubljana 336(4)(0.034.2) CAPRIROLO, Gonzalo Financial crisis in euro area and policy response [Elektronski vir] / Gonzalo Caprirolo and Jože Markič. - El. knjiga. - Ljubljana : Institute of Macroeconomic Analysis and Development, 2015. -(Working paper series / IMAD; 2015,1) ISBN 978-961-6839-27-3 (pdf) 1. Markič, Jože 278437888 CONTENTS 1 Introduction...........................................................................................................................................1 2 Type and causes of the crisis.................................................................................................................2 3 Financial integration, leverage build up and banking freeze.............................................................7 4 The systemic financial crisis, its transmission and transactions of balance of payments...............17 5 Policy response to the crisis and the zero lower bound....................................................................30 6 Crisis and Contagion to Slovenia........................................................................................................43 7 Conclusions..........................................................................................................................................57 8 REFERENCES.........................................................................................................................................60 LIST OF FIGURE S Figure 1: Private debt in GDP in 2008..........................................................................................................................................................8 Figure 2: Total domestic banking sector assets in 2008........................................................................................................................8 Figure 3: Gross capital flows (euroarea peripheral countries)............................................................................................................11 Figure 4: Liabilities of peripheral countries credit institutions, 12-nnonths accumulated flows.............................................12 Figure 5: Liabilities of peripheral countries' credit institutions broken down by instruments (12-month accumulated flows)....................................................................................................................................................................................................................13 Figure 6: Peripheral countries bank deposits and securities issued.................................................................................................13 Figure 7: Peripheral (GIIPS) countries borrowing and liabilities (loans and securities issued).................................................15 Figure 8: ECB lending to credit institutions.............................................................................................................................................15 Figure 9: Bank liabilities to euroarea residents (loans and securities issued)...............................................................................16 Figure 10: Peripheral countries net financial transactions and current account.........................................................................19 Figure 11: Peripheral countries net financial transactions and current account.........................................................................19 Figure 12: Peripheral countries balance of payments..........................................................................................................................20 Figure 13: Peripheral countries net financial transactions..................................................................................................................21 Figure 14: Peripheral countries gross capital inflows and current account...................................................................................23 Figure 15: Peripheral countries gross capital outflows........................................................................................................................23 Figure 16: Credit activity, asset prices and foreign liabilities in GIIPS countries...........................................................................25 Figure 17: Share price indices......................................................................................................................................................................26 Figure 18: Change in foreign liabilities due to valuation.....................................................................................................................26 Figure 19: Peripheral countries current accout and valuation changes of liabilities..................................................................27 Figure 20: Peripheral countries current accout and valuation changes of assets........................................................................28 Figure 21: Credit activity, stock exchange and valuation changes in GIIPS countries................................................................28 Figure 22: Current account balance in peripheral countries..............................................................................................................30 Figure 23: Banking system's external liabilities......................................................................................................................................32 Figure 24: Private capital inflows in Slovenia..........................................................................................................................................46 Figure 25: Private and government capital inflows in Slovenia........................................................................................................46 Figure 26: Net international investment position of Slovenia...........................................................................................................47 Figure 27: External debt (government and banks) of Slovenia.........................................................................................................47 Figure 28: Gross capital inflows, valuation adjustments and current account of Slovenia.......................................................48 Figure 29: Real echange rate and nominal labor cost..........................................................................................................................48 Figure 30: Target liabilities of Slovenia......................................................................................................................................................49 Figure 31: Accumulated growth..................................................................................................................................................................49 Figure 32: Correlation between total bank liabilities and private credit growth.........................................................................50 Figure 33: Growth of external debt, total whole sale, private credit and private deposits.......................................................50 Figure 34: Correlation between external borrowing and and private credit gowth...................................................................51 Figure 35: Correlation between external borrowing and and private credit gowth...................................................................51 Figure 36: Correlation between wholesale borrowing and and private credit gowth...............................................................52 Figure 37: Correlation between wholesale borrowing and and private credit gowth...............................................................52 Figure 38: Slovenia outstanding amounts at the end of the period (stocks). Figure 39: Capital adequacy (core tier 1) of Slovenia............................................. Figure 40: Demand for loans......................................................................................... Figure 41: Non-financial corporate performance of Slovenia............................. Figure 42: Selected financial structure indicators of Slovenia............................ Figure 43: Selected indebtedness indicators of Slovenia..................................... Figure 44: Selected cash flows and margin indicators of Slovenia.................... Figure 45: Selected cash flows and margin indicators of Slovenia.................... ..53 ..53 ..54 ..54 ..55 ..55 ..56 ..56 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS CAC EA EBITDA ECB EC EFSF ESM ESRB EU GDP GIIPS IMF LTRO OECD OTR REER SP SRF SSM TARGET UK US Collective Action Clauses Euro area Earnings Before Interest, Taxes, Depreciation and Amortization European Central Bank European Commission European Financial Stability Facility European Stability Mechanism European Systematic Risk Board European union Gross domestic product Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain International Monetary Fund Long term refinancing operations The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Outright Monetary Transactions Real effective exchange rate Stability Program Single Resolution Fund Single Supervisory Mechanism Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross Settlement Express Transfer System United Kingdom United States Povzetek Razprave o vzrokih finančne krize so tudi po šestih letih še vedno aktualne. Finančna kriza je nastala zaradi delovanja več dejavnikov: prekomerni fiskalni primanjkljaji, poslabšanje konkurenčnosti gospodarstva, neravnovesje tekočih računov plačilne bilance, nenadni obrat kapitalskih tokov in bančna kriza. V delovnem zvezku analiziramo finančno krizo in neravnovesja evrskega območja, nastala zaradi prezadoženosti perifernih držav {angl. peripheral countries), ki so si brez vključenega tveganja in nadzora finančna sredstva izposojala iz držav takoimenovanega jedra {angl. core countries). Ekonomska politika si je prizadevala ponovno ovrednotiti breme dolga, saj je s krizo nastalo nezaupanje na medbančnih trgih. Tako je ECB leta 2012 poleg nadaljnjih ukrepov dolgoročnega refinanciranja začela izvajati še program OMT, na osnovi katerega je na sekudarnem trgu kupovala kratkoročne državne obveznice evrskih držav. Ob negotovosti glede vrzdržnosti javnega dolga in omejenem dostopu do trgov financiranja je potrebno poleg monetarne unije vzpostaviti tudi skupni fiskalni stabilizacijski mehanizem. Breme zunanje dolga zasebnega sektorja se je namreč preneslo na državni sektor, kateremu se je skrčil fiskalni prostor (konsolidacija). Ekonomska politika mora zato uravnavati zmerno razdolževanje in spodbuditi agregatno povpraševanje, ki bo pospešilo gospodarsko rast in odpravilo neravnovesje. Summary Six years since the outset of the crisis its nature in the euro area is still hotly debated. Views include fiscal prolificacy, lack of competitiveness, current account imbalances, sudden stop of capital and banking crisis. The paper argues that the crisis in the euro area since the outset has been financial and systemic, taking place on the background of a leveraged private sector financed from the core of the euro area and highly integrated financial system without integrated risk monitoring. The underlying diagnosis underpinning the policy response only recognized the systemic dimension of the crisis at a very late stage. The policy response pursued the redefinition of debt burden sharing arrangements against private creditors at the time of major crisis of confidence and in absence of relevant backstop facilities for government and banks. This triggered self-fulfilling crisis expectations that put at stake the existence of the monetary union. It was required the effective ECB communication on Outright Monetary Transactions in 2012 to move the euro area away of a such an adverse equilibria. The euro area emerging institutional architecture provides a stronger set up to deter and to cope with future potential systemic financial crisis. Yet, the crisis has revealed that member states in absence of a lender of last resort function are subject to destabilizing speculation and some have practically narrow or no margin of maneuver to offset shocks requiring the completion of the monetary union with a common fiscal stabilizing mechanism. The existence of such an arrangement and of devising a single fiscal stance at euro area level is particularly relevant in the post crisis period. This is because private debt burden has been transformed into public one reducing fiscal space and there is weak aggregate demand requiring policies that contribute to a conducive environment for an orderly deleveraging and correcting imbalances. "A passer-by sees a man looking under a lamppost and asks what he is trying to find. "My keys," he replies. They look for a while but find nothing. The passer-by asks whether the first man is sure he lost his keys here. "Oh, no," 1 INTRODUCTION This paper looks at the causes, propagation and financial adjustment to the systemic financial crisis still affecting the euro area; the first systemic financial crisis of the common currency area with its origin in the banking sector. The focus of the paper is on the common drivers of the process and to a lesser extent on country specific conditions of euro area members which contributed to crisis and its propagation (i.e. mainly highly leveraged financial institutions, private sector debt build up and prior misallocation of financial resources). This is because the crisis from the outset can be regarded as systemic to the monetary union although affecting member states with different degree and direction. Recognizing the common dimension of the crisis is a key to understand the evolution of events, spillovers and deepness. It is likely that such a crisis would not have taken place under a different policy set up in which countries would have enjoyed independent monetary policy and faced a fragmented or more narrow financial investor base such as that existing prior to monetary union. The consequences of the crisis and its deepness would have been also lessened if at an early stage its common, systemic nature and financial dimension would have been recognized and addressed. The emphasis is placed on the common dimension of the crisis to euro area member states, since it was generated in conditions in which countries shared the following conditions: lacked independent monetary policy; exhibited strong financial integration which underpinned the high leverage of financial institutions and their clients; faced light financial regulation and low interest rates. Thus the approach followed highlights the importance of the common policy response, as the fate of the monetary union and member states is collective. This does not neglect the importance of country specific conditions and policy effort in handling the crisis. However, since financial panic and loss of confidence are at its core, creating and fostering confidence required a comprehensive and swift response at supra national level (e.g. effective backstop to government debt). This came only at late stage when the crisis already threatened the very existence of the monetary union due to the fear that individual member states lacked the fiscal capacity to handle the disproportion of the crisis. The policy response at euro area level aimed at minimizing cross border fiscal costs related to potential bailout by means of redefining debt burden sharing arrangements between creditor and debtors amidst and fueling the confidence crisis. This resulted in the coordination of decentralized lender decisions into coordinated self-fulfilling crisis behavior, run on liabilities of vulnerable member states and thus fragmentation of the monetary union and payment system. The paper argues that the crisis was triggered by financial panic resulting in a sudden banking funding stop and reversal of funding flows leading to systemic banking crisis in the euro area. Such a crisis can be regarded as one in which the entire financial system of the whole monetary area is engulfed (Gorton 2012) affecting the workings of pre-crisis financial channels. The nature of crisis since its origins has been financial. Its evolution reflects the intertwining of the policy responses at euro area and country levels, country specific vulnerabilities (e.g. reliance on euro area financial funding) and relative strength of fundamentals. Although the crisis can be regarded due to its sequencing as: banking, country-specific sovereign debt and monetary union crisis, in reality it can be said that from the outset it was a systemic crisis of the monetary union. One of the most visible traces of its systemic nature is the strong disintegration of cross border banking flows. The impact of the crisis in the euro area member countries is reflected on changes in the pattern of balance of payment transactions, including those transactions registered in the Eurosystem TARGET2, adjustment in sectors' balance sheets, economic activity, employment, renationalization of banking sector and other relevant variables. The paper traces the impact of the banks funding shock and its propagation as mirrored on various balance of payment transactions of different sectors of vulnerable euro area member states. It is argued that transactions of balance of payments reflect the buildup of vulnerabilities and the impact of the dramatic disruption on financial flows (the common factor) rather than causing the crisis. Country specific external accounts capture the interaction of the common disruption of financial flows and the net structural borrower positions and vulnerabilities (idiosyncratic factor) buildup before the crisis, when as a result of monetary union the financial sector was strongly integrated, risk perception improved and access to funding was relatively easy (e.g. leading to private sector leverage). Transactions of balance of payments capture the following: the impact of the discontinuity of financial flows affecting originally banks and financial intermediaries (i.e. financial crisis) in the common currency area; the mutation of the sudden stop of capital into sovereign debt crisis and; the manifestation of the crisis into an explicit crisis of the currency union putting at risk its very existence. Thus, balance of payments' transactions mirror the adjustment of various sectors to the sudden stop of capital, successive multiple shocks and confidence erosion resulting from worsening conditions and risk perception of institutions, member states and monetary union. The paper documents how the policy response to the crisis contributed to its propagation and mitigation only at a later stage. In the context of the sequencing of events, it looks at contagion and spillovers and how the vulnerabilities intensified and also affected Slovenia which built imbalances in the run to the crisis. The paper is divided in five sections. The first looks at the type and causes of the euro crisis. The second dwells on overall financial conditions at the outset of the crisis. The third section traces the change in financial conditions brought by the crisis to the transactions in the balance of payments of peripheral countries. The fourth section looks at the policy response at the euro area level and its impact on the crisis, spillovers and mitigation. The fifth section focuses on how Slovenia coped with its own policy challenges amidst the profound change in conditions brought by the euro area crisis and contagion. The last section concludes. 2 TYPE AND CAUSES OF THE CRISIS An appropriate diagnosis of the causes of the crisis affecting the euro area and its members is of outmost importance as well as assessing the suitability of the type and timing of policy measures addressing it to understand its evolution. From the outset focusing the policy response on the financial and systemic dimension of the crisis to avoid the adverse consequences of underestimating the risks for overall economy and recovery of euro area would have been desirable. Yet, six years since the onset of the international crisis its nature in the monetary union is still being debated. As such risk have been underestimated as reflected in the evolution of the policy response including until recently the reluctance of creating a backstop facility to shoulder the financial burden of addressing capitalization and resolution of banks and thus disentangle the link between sovereigns and banks. There are various examples of the different views of the nature of the crisis. According to an editorial of the Financial Times (May 2013) the real problems of the euro area lie in excessive current account imbalances, disintegration of banking union and weak growth but not on fiscal discipline with the exception of Greece. On the other hand according to Wyplosz (2013) the euro area crisis is not caused by issues such as competitiveness but is the lack of fiscal discipline broadly defined to include adequate banking supervision. According to Philipon (2014) some economists see the crisis as driven by fiscal indiscipline, others by external imbalances and sudden stops of capital, and others by excessive private leverage. Given the different views regarding the causes of the crisis and state of the economy, it can be argued that the risks for individual countries and as such for the overall monetary union are still present as policy response are devised upon a diagnosis of underlying challenges. The implicit diagnosis and perception policy makers had about the reasons of the crisis since its outburst can be traced out from the sequencing and type of policy responses. They have so far included: i) strengthening the fiscal framework for budgetary surveillance through the Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance (2011) and so-called "Six-pack" (i.e. fiscal dimension); ii) tackling macroeconomic imbalances though the so-called Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure (with a range of indicators emphasizing competitiveness); iii) creation of the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) to avert the instability of the financial system^; and iv) endorsing a banking union (2013) to address the vulnerabilities and tensions of co-existence of banks operating in a financially integrated space but located in members states with relatively limited or strained fiscal capacity. The later included the establishment of a Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) through the attribution of banking supervision tasks to the ECB and creation of a Single Bank Resolution Fund. In direct relation to the crisis two financial stabilization mechanisms were created with relative small financial power: the European Financial Stabilization Mechanism (EFSM) and the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF). In 2012 they were replaced by a permanent rescue mechanism the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). The euro area policy response evolved towards one that recognized the systemic nature of the crisis and the weaknesses of design of the monetary union (i.e. common dimension). Nevertheless, policy response at euro area's level still falls short to fully dispel concerns about the reasons underlying the crisis, to speed up adjustment and sustained the strength of recovery of the monetary union. This includes the lack of single banking deposit insurance system. Similarly, the roles of fiscal transfers and issuance of common debt to underpin the strength of monetary union are still anathema while the aggregate policy mix so far has failed to create a conducive macroeconomic environment to facilitate adjustment and private sector deleveraging in vulnerable countries increasing the risk of a protracted crisis. There are two main views regarding the origin of the crisis at euro area level. One points out to fiscal policy and the other to the drivers of balance of payment dynamics including those flows registered in TARGET2 system. Within the later there are two views, one pointing at competitiveness and the other to the role of capital flows. The view holding that the crisis in euro area was caused by fiscal profligacy seems to be marginal and valid mostly in the case of Greece. Among those suggesting the role of balance of payments, one points out at current account transactions and the role of competitiveness (minority view) and the other at financial account transactions and the role of capital flows. There are also some conciliatory views recognizing the validity of both arguments in explaining the crisis and argue for a third one related to the so-called redenomination risk or the risk of a re-emergence of national currencies in euro area (for a review of the literature Cecchetti et.al. (2012)). The view that the crisis in euro area is a balance of payment crisis associated with loss of competitiveness has been forcefully put forward by German economists Sinn and Wollmershauser. According to Sinn (2014) the lack of competitiveness of Southern European countries and France is the underlying problem of the unresolved financial crisis. Sinn and Wollmershauser (2011, 2012a) claim thatTARGET2 imbalances (on our view reflecting mainly outflows of capital from euro area peripheral countries without counterpart of capital inflows) are the result of a classical balance-of-payments imbalance (Sinn and Wollmershauser (2012b). Their argument is that current account imbalances of the peripheral countries, financed by creation of money, are reflected in the increase in TARGET2 liabilities (Sinn and Wollmershauser 201 ^ The macro imbalances process implicitly replaces the role of exchange rate in signaling and adjusting excess aggregate demand or structural problems by focusing among other indicators on performance of export, labor and product markets. The ESRB is an institutional arrangement, aiming at identifying asset prices and credit bubbles driven by financial exuberance, capital flows and credit in a globalized world which also lay at the hearth of developments in competitiveness. ^ "..the increase in Target liabilities created by the additional creation of money in these countries was of a magnitude that financed the current account deficits" ^ According to Deutsche Bank 2011 below the surface of the euro area's public debt and banking crisis lies a balance-of-payments crisis caused by the misalignment of internal real exchange. Furthermore, according to Sinn (2012) the ECB might have caused capital flight as it replaced private flows to finance current account deficits."'The other main view explaining the crisis points out at the role of capital flows and reversal of outstanding stock of cross border claims. It includes authors such as Buiter et al (2011), Mody and Bornhorst (2012), Bindseil and König (2012), Cecioni and Ferrero (2012), and Pisani-Ferri and l\/lerler(2012). The fundamental question is whether the nature of the current crisis in the euro area is indeed a current account's balance crisis triggered by perceived unsustainable current account position and loss of competitiveness of particular member states or a financial crisis triggered by the collapse and erosion of confidence of financial market participants and reflected in the capital account. If it is the latter case the sequencing would be a financial crisis that first affected financial intermediaries and caused a sudden stop of capital, then it became the first banking crisis in the common currency area, turned into sovereign debt crisis and in a later stage manifested in an explicit crisis of the monetary union. The answer to this question contributes to understand the appropriateness of policy response at the euro area and member state level and in particular in light of the fiscal capacity of individual member states to deal with a crisis affecting the monetary union. Prior to the crisis the notion that an euro area member would be subject-to-balance of payment crisis and of the persistence of current account imbalances was not controversial. This issue was regarded as an important "unknown unknown" concerning the monetary union by Pisani-Ferri and Merler (2012). In their view the events in euro area since 2009 suggests the existence of such a possibility.Concering the literature, Garber (1998) and Kenen (1999) are some of the few economists addressing the issue of balance of payment crisis in a monetary union. In the first case, the envisaged crisis scenario was one of speculative attack and not of a current account balance driven crisis. In particular, it was envisaged some form of attack due to different effect to business cycle shocks and reluctance of a given national central bank to provide unlimited credit.^ In the second case, two triggers were identified: The reluctance of a given euro area member's central bank to increase claims (which in fact is not at discretion of individual central banks members of the ECB) against a country running current account deficits (i.e. intra-EMU imbalances); and internal opposition to monetary union in a given country. It seems that both contributions point out to the vulnerabilities of the monetary union to the interruption of the common currency payment system and lackof a centralized lender of last resort to underpin it rather than to a balance of payment crisis associated to transactions settled in foreign currency and sustainability of current account. The issue is that a balance of payment crisis involves the lack of foreign currency to settle external transactions, massive outflows of capital in terms of foreign currency or depletion of external reserves. In a monetary union individual central banks do not hold external reserves while settlement of transactions, domestic and cross border among member states takes place in the domestic common currency issued by the common monetary authority. Those transactions are settled in a centralized platform to which central banks of member states are part. Therefore, it is not clear whether the crisis in the euro area could at all be interpreted as balance of payment crisis caused or triggered by the perception of unsustainable current account imbalances. As long as member states hold, generate within (credit intermediation) or have access " "the ECB compensated for, and may even have caused, capital flight inasmuch as it replaced expensive foreign interbank credit with cheaper credit from the local electronic printing presses, and helped maintain and prolong structural current-account deficits that otherwise would have been difficult to finance" ^ In formulating the attack scenario Garber refers to the Bundesbank unwillingness to provide unlimited credit at the time of collapse ofERMin 1992. to flows of common currency deriving from commercial or financial transactions including those facilitated by central bank operations their cross border transactions can be carried out uninterruptedly. In the world of no-monetary union the impact of foreign trade and financial transactions on money creation depends importantly upon the type of exchange rate regime in place. In the case of a monetary union the impact of commercial and financial transactions among its members are reflected automatically in money creation and as such are undistinguishable from the impact of domestic financial transactions and financial intermediation. Given that domestic central banks in a monetary union do not accumulate external reserves arising from trade and capital flows among members, which will be the case in a fixed exchange rate regime or a currency board which is extremely dangerous in a world of free and volatile capital flows, this implies that current account crisis cannot take place. What can occur in a common currency and among its members is a shock, interruption or reversal of financial flows among members leading to liquidity, insolvency and debt crises.6 In such events, to the extent that the ECB does not provide liquidity to solvent banks to facilitate domestic and cross border transaction the payment system can be interrupted and potentially lead to collapse of institutions. Furthermore, the interruption of cross border funding when affecting the sovereigns in a monetary union can become serious, leading to debt crisis to the extent that they cannot monetize government debt because of lack of independent monetary policy. Depending of a member states' intrinsic vulnerabilities, particularly depending on the leverage of its various sectors, severe adverse shocks can affect the capacity of generating flows and holdings of common currency. This is particularly the case under an episode of sudden stop of capital. As a consequence, balance sheet adjustments of various sectors of the economy would ensue with real impact on the economy. The adjustment would consist of repairing the capacity to generate and attract domestic currency to enable the financing of domestic and cross border transactions rather than to accumulate external reserves to facilitate external trade alone. Thus a massive adverse financial shock (sudden stop of capital) affecting balance sheets of various sectors (i.e. particularly those leveraged) would generate a similar adjustment process in terms of balance sheet strengthening of the private sector than in the case of a balance of payment crisis. However, the adjustment would concern not only the balance sheet strengthening of those entities engaged in foreign trade but also of all entities, including viable leveraged ones, whose liquidity and refinancing risk increase given to an adverse change in overall liquidity conditions in the common currency. In such circumstances preserving the integrity of the payment system is of outmost importance. Therefore, the appropriate policy implications should be drawn not only taking into account balance of payment statistics but the entire balance sheets of various sectors and entities and their interaction within and across borders. The fact that post-crisis adjustment in current account imbalances in peripheral counties has been slower than the sharp correction in countries that underwent typical balance of payment crisis also reflects the fact that holdings of foreign currency are not the underlying budget constraint to finance cross border transactions but holdings of domestic common currency to settle domestic and cross border transactions. Given that domestic and cross border transactions among euro area members are settled in a common currency, there is no currency risk and thus credit risk and creditworthiness become essential when engaging in internal and external financial transactions. Also in a monetary union where large troubled financial institutions are not perceived as to big-to-fail or to the extent that governments enjoy enough capacity to provide backstop to large financial entities in case of need, domestic and cross border transactions should not be massively interrupted but the impact should be restricted mainly to the '■This is particularly the case when decentralized individual decisions get coordinated by common event, factor or other type of trigger. troubled institution and its respective creditors. However, prior to the crisis the risk perception was blurred by the massive size ofcapital flows among developed countries and particularly among euro area members and by the buoyant economic conditions they created. Furthermore the crisis revealed the huge indebtedness of financial entities, banking systems that in size are various multiples of their countries respective GDPs and of the private sector. This, in the context of the sudden stop and coordination of expectations that it created, made of the to-big-to fail entities not the exception with important potential impact on governments' balance sheets. From the outset such a huge vulnerability put a premium on policies that would maintain confidence and financial integration and which would ensure an orderly deleveraging of private sector and thus the survival of the monetary union. In particular, the systemic and financial nature of the crisis put a premium on policies that would defuse the coordination of self-fulfilling crisis expectations that underpinned the propagation of the crisis. In the absence of foreign currency to settle transactions among euro area members characterizing the crisis as one of balance of payments does not make sense. This might explain why in the pre-crisis period such a possibility received relatively low attention from the academia. A more accurate characterization of the crisis seems to be of a financial crisis with impact on payment system and financial flows. The possibility of a systemic banking or financial crisis in a monetary union on the back of confidence erosion also seems not to have been explored at large. Regarding the possibility of a banking crisis in a wide monetary union and contagion there were early concerns about the capacity of a decentralized system in euro area to deal with crisis management and with wide systemic implications (e.g. Prati et al. 1999). Evidence also points out at policymakers becoming increasingly aware of European systemic financial risk and of their concerns regarding the limitations of at that time exiting decentralized institutional set up to deal with it (Schinasi 2007). Yet, the policy focus seems to have been more on cross-border burden sharing rather than on a systemic financial crisis and policies to address it. In particular, various key issues of a systemic financial crisis were not explored. For example, dealing with contagion and the consequences of the unprecedented retreat of cross border banking activity; defusing coordination of expectations that become self-fulfilling; the impact on the economy and the financial capacity of individual sovereigns to deal with massive financial shock and impact on their balance sheets (i.e. too-big-to fail) without independent central banks and; the role of EU state aid framework in the event of financial crisis. Another dimension that seems to have also received less attention was the vulnerability arising from private sector indebtedness including to big-to-fail institutions to shocks. In this paper the view is that the crisis as reflected in balance of payments accounts of core and vulnerable countries and TARGET2 is systemic, it has its origin in the financial system and was triggered by panic. The collapse of confidence and appropriate policy response to tackle it has being the key ingredient spreading and propagating the crisis. Balance of payment accounts reflect the transmission and propagation of the financial crisis encompassing also sovereign debt. As such balance of payments accounts are not the cause but the effect of a profound crisis of confidence originated in the deep disruption of an integrated global financial system (i.e. banking system) that took place on the backof ex-post visible highly leverage position of private sector in at that time highly integrated euro area. According to Gorton (2012), a financial crisis takes place when banks' debt holders run on such a debt. This definition can be extended and applied to the run of holders on government debt, such as that experienced by some euro area countries, particularly from other euro area residents, leading to shrinkage of the euro area government debt market and widening of debt spreads. More broadly, if in the context of the monetary union the risk of currency redenomination is also taken into account, a systemic financial crisis can be understood as an event in which investors run away from all type of liabilities from sectors or countries perceived as risl