REFERENCES BRECKA.S (IWl 'FicHiibool Slovak Trleviunn" I'npuWivhcd pop« cklnetcd aK'ollo>|uiumon ihc RmnHlu-ring of TckvisBin in Eavi-t'cninil Europe. l.onn: Fad and Fantasy" in Vdianovtki.C. ed Freedom in Bmadcastrng London. Institute of Eeommuc Affait». 17*-207 (KX)DWIN, P 11992) -Did the ITC »ave British public service bruadcasting''" in Media. Culture and Societl. sol 14. no. 3. 653-«l. GOODWIN. P 11993) "The luture ol the BBt^' in Media. Culture and Society, snl 1.5 no 3 497-302. GRAHAM. A AND DAVIES. G (I»'I2I "Hw PuWic Funding of Broadcasting" in Congdon. T et al ed« Paying lor BtoadcaMing. The HandbiHliti-cal reconstruction and econimic restructuring imperilled again the existence of civil scKiety. Deregulation and privatization of national economy and the media - particularly the press - are considered by the new power elites in Central-Eastern Europe not only as fundamental prerequisites to solve the weaknesses of bureaucratic control and achieve a higher level of productivity, but also as necessary conditions of general democratization and, thus, the autonomy and development of the media. Arguments for such changes are similar to those prevailing in Western Europe (cf. Keane, 1991) and already domesticatcil in some developing countries. In the classical liberal model of the media, their primary demwratic role is defined in terms of a waichdog function; accordingly, the media ought to control, and limit the power of, the state authorities. It is precisely this function which determines forms of ownership and organization of the media. Since the primary task is to safeguard the autonomy of the media from the state, and since only the private property is said to ensure such an autonomy, the fundamental condition for a democratic media system is its firm, and exclusive foundation in the free market. Any state or public regulation may essentially limit the critical role of the media. While such a regulation is believed to have been "acceptable" in broadcasting in the period of technological limitations (e.g.. because of the "scarcity of frequencies"). contemporary developments in communication technologies (e.g.. satellites and cable systems) now support a complete independence of the electronic media from the state, too. The lihend model of media autonomy The classical liberal model is based on several normative and historical (partially implicit) assumptions, which is completely neglected by the new Eastern European (de)regulation endeavours. At least four of them should be mentioned here: (1) In accordance with the traditional conception of the relationship between the state and civil society, where the latter included citizens as the owners of the production means, the critical role of the media as "instruments" of civil society was understood in terms of limiting, and preventing the abuses, of state power. The task of the media was to control and limit the principle of maximization of political power. (2) Before the rise of the mass press on the eve of the 19th century (Splichal 1981a. p. 99). the press was highly politicized and clearly related to party interests. The growth of the mass press and particularly radio and television in the 20th century generated depoliticization of the media and their commercialization based on the growing importance of their entertainment function. This trend obviously challenged traditional liberal conceptions restricted to the political role of the media. (3) Traditional divisions between the state and civil stxriety were challenged by the development of new media functions-entertainment and. particularly, advertising - and the economic restructuring of advanced capitalist societies. Similar to the state, agents of "invisible power" (capital), their transnational agglomeration, and the principle of profit maximization they tend to advance, jeopardize the independence of the media and journalists, and Ihe freedom and equality of citizens. (4) Processes of oligopolization and monopolization in the economy and. specifically. in the media have changed the traditional relationship of independence among the state, capital, and the media. While traditionally, the state wanted to avoid public media control and penetrate the media (e.g.. by legal regulation), now it cooperates with media conglomerates which, on their part, try to influence governments and to get governmental support for their projects. The controversies related to these assumptions make the validity of classical liberal conceptions of the media dubious. As for example Harber (1992. p. 63) demonstrates, "importing free political parties, parliaments, and presses cannot establish a democratic civil society; imposing a free market may even have the opposite effect." Uncritical imitation of democratic institutions developed in older democratic institutions may be a risky business. Instead, as Dahl (1991. p. 15) suggests, the countries in transition to the inauguration of democratic institutions should "discriminate between the aspects of the mature demwratic countries that are essential to democracy and those that are not only not essential to it but may be harmful." There is no doubt that a centralized socialist economy based on state ownership was both economically inefficient and inimical to democracy. But it would also be mistaken to believe that "free markets" and private property are the only (or. at least, the best) alternative in both respects. Although an advocacy of any form of socialized markets and social ownership is regarded w ith considerable suspicion in the period of the proclaimed lai.isez-faire doctrine in East-Central Europe, it should be acknowledged, as Blackburn (1991. p. 234) claims, that "the imposition of narrow commercial criteria menaces the integrity of civil society and hands the initiative to rapctween the economic sphere (of civil stxiety) and Ihe political sphere of the state is fully developed in Western capitalist societies. As a number of studies report, the contents of privately owned televison stations (still) diverge significantly from those of public corporations in terms of structure and values. However, public broadca.ster do not strengthen their distinctive image of serious public affairs journalism, cultural programming and educational programming vis-a-vis commercial stations. On the contrary, they largely yield to the competitive pressures of commercial stations and include more fiction and other "de-nationalized" lightweight entertainment programs. As an NBC executive in the USA pointed out. "a network cannot bow to higher standards if its competitors all round adopt lower ones. It becomes a greyer issue when it's all around you, and you're the last person crying Wait a minute"" (Blunder 1991. p. 9). In teh former socialist countries in East-Central Europe, this contradiction is partly "softened" by the absence of a truly developed market economy, and the continuing domination of the state over the economy. At the same time, however, the contradiction is strengthened by the low level of investment in domestic programming. Rising production costs lead to an increase in less expensive imported commercial programs transmitted by "public" television stations. Tlius the contradiction between the state and civil society in the media sphere is not just a question of (formal) ownership and control; it is much more a question of values and ideologies dominating the global market. One of the main questions we have to address is whether, and how, a "postso-cialist" civil society can be constructed to "deregulate" the dependence of the I 1 83 Tcori)« in pf»ku. Icl Ml. Si. 11 12. I^uMiana 1993 mcdiii on the state andVor the market, and to maximize freedom of communication. The situation in East-Central Europe differs from that in the West at least in one crucial dimension. While in the West democratic efforts are aimed particularly at decommodification of the media and limitation of profit-maximizing principle. East-Central Europe is facing only the first consequences of de-nationalization and privatization. Commercial motives of the media are thus often regarded as mainly limiting state penetration, without having any unfavourable conseciuenccs. Journalists see media commercialization as an important instrument to achieve their own autonomy from the state, while the question of how the media care for the interests of the citizens is beyond their "professional" interest. The basic problem is the lack of money and capital needed for a practically efficient, not only a nominal privatization, rather than the danger of an excessive power of capital. This makes very feasible a monopolistic coalition between the state and media professionals (journalists); although the latter may now play a more important role than in the former system where a similar coalition existed, the both systems would have in common the exclusion of the third part - the audiences. The domination of any of these three groups - the state, media professionals, and audiences - or coalition between two of them against the third one inevitably produces the imbalance of power and domination of interests of minority (in authoritarian systems) or majority (in paternalistic systems) against the interests of those not participating in the coalition. In his early writings on freedom of the press, Marx criticized the liberal conception of freedom of the press, which reduced it to. or subsumed it under, freedom of entrepreneurship. At the same time, however, he admitted that "it is no transgression, when a German perceives the unknown goddess of freedom of the press as one of the goddesses be already knows, and accordingly he names her after them, freedom of entrepreneurship or freedom of ownership" (Marx 1974, p. 68). This is exactly the case with the contemporary situation in East-Central Europe after the decades of non-market economy and state controlled media and economy. It is largely believed that freedom of ownership and. particularly, private ownership is the guarantor of demiKracy and free press. Privatization is seen as the only instrument to reduce and. possibly, abolish state intervention in the media. Private ownership is simply the only "goddess" known and experienced by the majority of people, although to a very limited extent While freedom of the press was declared as one of the fundamental freedoms (though not of individuals) under the previous regimes, private ownership was banished; now the gcxldess of private ownership resurrected as did the religion itself. On the other hand, social and economic equality which was the highest value in socialism, is devaluated by the anti-communist "movements" or even declared to be a negative value. Similarly to socialsm which neglected, in contrast to Marx s ideas, the culturally progressive side of capitalist expansion (Garnham 1992. p. 3) and developed essentially as aniicapiialuim. aniicomniiinism now represents "a total negation of socialist values, the suppression of the entire Marxism and not only Leninism, the rejection of contractual and cooperative relations, and forcing of egoism, competitiveness, and private ownership" (Rus 1992. p. 21). Apparently, the media in East-Central Europe are not yet dominated by commercial corporate speech - mainly because the process of de-nationalization and privatization of the former state and party owned media is far from being completed - but they continue to exist under another form of domination. The actual autonomy of the media is limited by the state which tries to exhibit and strengthen its sovereignty. In a way. Oast-Central European media are in similar position as those in capitalist countries: on the one hand, they are under the persisting pressure of state censorship and control; on the other hand, they are exposed to the "self-contradictory and self-paralysing tendencies of market-ba.sed communications media" (Keane 1991. p. 116). Thus, the fundamental question of whether a genuinely democratic communication system can be worked out may be (and should be) addressed simultaneously to both capitali.st (commercial) and postsoci-alist (paternalistic-commercial) systems. Democratic perspectives of the media in postsocialisni The fundamental difference between the two media systems - the Western capitalist commercial system and the emerging paternal-commercial system in postsocialist countries - is in the fact that East-Central European societies have never experienced political democracy in any full sense. With the exception of Hungary and. partly. Poland which has been often split between Austria. Russia and Prussia, they represented for centuries stateless nations, although with different degrees of autonomy: Bulgarians. Romanians. Serbs and Montenegrians, until the fall of the Ottoman Empire, following the war between Russia and Turkey; Czechs. Slovaks. Slovenians and Croatians until the end of the First World War and the fall of Austro-1 lungarian Monarchy. Both multinational empires were actually destroyed by nationalisms. Similarly to the other two great empires having dominated in Eastern Europe, Russia - though independent itself - always represented the "jail of nations". Political democratization which started in some of these countries after the First World War was blocked by the Second, and after the end of war by Soviet occupation (w ith the exception of Yugoslavia), As Walzer (1992, p, 164) argues, the internationalism of communists, which was aimed against imperialism of "great empires" and their dynasties, actually owes a great deal precisely to that imperialism. The absence of any fully developed democratic tradition certainly prevents these countries from establishing an indigenous political demwracy compatible with the nature of their ow n culture(s). The lack of other - mainly economic and technological - resources makes dependency road even more likely to be followed by East-Central European countries. Thus Sparks is right when saying that by "looking at what is entailed in the profitable operation of the press and broadcasting in a developed market economy we can perhaps gain some insight into the future development of the media in Ihe emerging market economies" (Sparks 1991. p. 13). This does not imply that East European societies will simply follow the path traced by those in the West, due to both internal and external (global) limits to growth. However, it does mean that external patterns of growth and "progress" are so powerful that peripheral societies like those in Ea.st-Central Europe cannot compete with them successfully. At best they can react and adapt to change in a rational way, but their autonomy or rationality is limited to certain "degrees of freedom" in implementing others' experiences and plans. The importance of differences between the two systems also applies to "market or democracy" dichotomy which has specific components in the former socialist countries, or even a different nature in comparison to the West, partly because democracy in East-Central Europe is (still) less endangered by the dominant commercial principle of profit maximization, partly because civil society seems to dispose of more indigenous power. The question of the kind of counter-power civil society has at its disposal is one of the main problems related to its autonomy from both the state and economy. In developed market systems the autonomy of civil society from economy seems problematic because huge economic p»l Cultttrv anJ thc liOAnoniK*»!!! Inlotmatuiit l.tmiliw. Sugv Sv* Yi»iU: V.tlniTi Pres» JAKI'HOWK /. KAROl ■'(-rum PinfugjiHlj I» Curpoialr Spnvh' Pcilnli JiMiiiulnm In SciTch iit j New Iilcnlll\. ~ Jttuln.tl iif ( •iilimunK-allun 47. .1: KhANl . Jims IWI lh< Mwdu jnJ DtiniH-tac» <'.imhml|ic Min Pro« l'IS.S CimI Vh-iciv ami ihc Sl;iU' NcwEuriijKan tdiltfil h> J Keane. l-<>ntk*n \"cT»»» KRI'titü K HANS P111 R ITOI RailKiil IXmivtali/jlh'n PiaTO Imrin-rtnmal 11. I IK^ <(> MliNt IMil R. lO/l 1W| -Pisnuj slmcnvUnm p.iiünK:nlu ~ Dilii (Soln.i piilofjl .AsiiuM 24 Ml'LCiAS (iL* iH Rl-V J 1 w|. CiHninuiiic.iii4)n jikI t uniiol Neiuoikv anü ilic New I conoiiuexol ruminunicaii-nn CambiHl^v P»ilil> Pic»« PRZtWORSKI. ADAM IWI l"i.lilii.-.il Dvn.iniii-»<'l l ivromiii-Rcloimv TJM jml S..ulh Pp 21 74 in Denuimi-c\ aiu] IVilitical IranslnimalitMi IlK'inio and l::>\|.(.enirul I iir •• Pp 1 |J. I2M in Nc» MciIm P'tltlKN < «»mpaliiliic IVr^Kcmc\ in \Ve\icin l-uriipc. ediicJ b\ I) Nk-Ouall jiHl K Sninc I iMidiHl Sage. Rl'S. VM.IKO I9/n'ii.i k.uniiiimiuniv med »iiNid» in .hI1u|iI»ii»nl. Sprmf iw:: 171 Wl Bl R MAX |l'»:4| l>)7(i Timaid a Si*R>l..)!> i.r ihc Piev, louliiul i>l Cummunicalinn 2A. 3: <»ft-HI| WII I.IAMS. RAYMOND I'l7n I ..niniiinKalfm» llaim<>nd»».>rlh Pcngmn ('idcdlluinl zi:l I NV MII.AN |WI Soumiak cc»k.>»l>ncn>kcli.i h.>«pbodo omejujejo. Pri tem država »pristaja« na skoraj popolno libcraliziicijo tiskanih medijev in obratno, elektronski mediji so praviloma izpostavljeni številnim nadzornim omejitvam. Pri tem jc definiranje statusa televizije kot nacionalnega medija posebej vprašljivo. Večina predlogov medijskih zakonov ' Sandra Baši«;, asnlcnlka na FDV I 1 89 Tcoliia m piakvi. lel .»n. U. 11-12. LiuMjana 19