Competition on the Global Market: A Way Towards an Autonomous International Court for Global Competition Cases Alen Balde Competition policy is a field where economists and lawyers have to work hand in hand to achieve efficiency and, in the international arena, global welfare. At the present, there is no internationally recognised of- ficial authority under the auspices of which there would take shape the global competition policy and, simultaneously, set up a core of global competition rules. Competition policy, still national or supranational in its nature, is, as a consequence, under strong influence of other na- tional or supranational policies and so regulated by various laws that in their specific way address competition cases including those with an international element. Overlapping of jurisdictions, conflicts between substantive and procedural laws are unavoidable. Considering that full and simultaneous compliance with all those laws is a hard task to fulfil, it makes cross-border transaction much more risky, time consuming, and costly than is necessary. By setting up an autonomous international court for global competition cases not only would we get rid obstacles to efficient enforcement of competition but we could make global wel- fare flourish without depriving developing countries of their economic growth. Key Words: Global competition, global market, international court, enforcement, World Trade Organization jEL Classification: K21, L40 Introduction In the era1 when ideas, goods, services flow without any difficulties through all around the World, when information about producers, prod- ucts or services they offer is easyily accessible, when it is less and less dangerous and risky to move the production to the countries where the costs of production are lower, the question that arises out is: can we really speak about global competition? With the difference to the regulation of international trade, there exist neither a set of international competition rules nor an international in- Alen Balde is a phü student at Faculty of Law, Business and Social Science, University of Glasgow, United Kingdom. Managing Global Transitions 6 (2): 207-222 stitution which would deal with global competition problems and solve competition cases with an international element. This leads us to the conclusion that at least for now we cannot, from the legal point of view, talk about global competition law or global competition policy. Hav- ing regulated international trade without considering or, rather, with- out having the necessary framework to consider, competition issues that arise from such a trade cause serious problems in legitimising any state's policy trying to preserve a high level of welfare for its citizens. Why is Global Competition Law Needed? Despite the fact that we cannot yet talk about global competition law2, this does not mean that competition on the global market does not exist. Before we look closer at the way in which international competition cases are dealt with, we should pose ourselves the question about justification to make competition on global level legally regulated. Considering that the us antitrust law was originally enacted not for preserving but stop- ping benefits deriving from competitive behaviour3, that perfect compe- tition and so perfect efficiency can never exist, someone could even think that competition law is something that can cause more evil than good. Further on we would see that there is even a bit of truth in this, which is the case if e. g. competition authorities or courts, when dealing with the competition issues, legitimise as competition policy those practices, or better those aims that undertakings try to achieve, and that have nothing to do with competition. Pure competition certainly does not need any regulation. Everyone is able to compete with his rivals in any way he finds efficient to win the pri- mary position over his rivals. Where this kind of practice can lead us, it is not difficult to imagine. Concentration of wealth, power, and the ability to decide about the quality of life of other people in the hands of some winners is something that should not be allowed. On the other hand, too much restriction of freedom of action and much higher protection of competitors than is necessary can cause the stagnation of progress and reduction of welfare. At what point of the scale between these two ex- tremes is the competition policy of the relevant market going to be at a certain period of time, it is hard to predict well in advance. Competition policy, which could be fully recognised only through decisions of com- petition authorities or court judgments, has never as its legitimate object just allocative efficiency. Through competition policy there are pursued also policies like social, environmental, employment and even political (e. g. achieving a single market in the eu).4 And as soon as there is a clash between various, in general allowed, recognisable policies it is hard to predict which of them is going to prevail and so decisively influence the decision of the case, except there, where the main objective of the sovereign institution which either makes or decides upon implementing various policies can be realised directly from hierarchically the highest le- gal act binding on it (e. g. achieving a common market in the ec Treaty). But how about deciding on a competition case in which there is present also an international element? This could happen in the fol- lowing cases: 1. National undertaking is acting and causing anticompetitive effects wholly outside national or supranational (e.g. the eu) territorial borders5 of the institution hearing the case. 2. Foreign undertaking is acting and causing (anti)competitive effects within the national or supranational territorial borders of the insti- tution hearing the case. 3. National or/and foreign undertaking is/are acting outside the na- tional or supranational territorial borders of the institution hearing the case but causing the anticompetitive effects within it. 4. National and foreign undertaking are both acting and causing (anti)competitive effects within and outside the national or supra- national territorial borders of the institution hearing the case (in- ternational merger). 5. National or foreign undertakings, each of them located and per- forming within different national or supranational territory and of- fering different products but at the same time enabling their cus- tomers access to all their products at once, which gives to this net- work a monopoly position (new-one network product). In one of these situations, the institution dealing with a case, would not, after deciding to have a jurisdiction to hear the case, immediately apply6 its competition law, but would be primarily balancing whether and to what extent national interests or, rather, the interests of its cus- tomers and undertakings, are affected compared with the interests of foreign ones. Taking into account that no institution would act against the national interests or in such a way as to reduce the welfare of its own citizens, in practice this means that in case 1 above, the institution is in general7 not going to prohibit the anticompetitive behaviour of its na- tional undertaking if the anticompetitive effects of such behaviour are going to rise and remain only and wholly outside its national or suprana- tional territorial borders without at the same time causing its home cus- tomers and consumers to be worse off.8 In this case foreign customers' and consumers' welfare is not considered9, which can have the effect that, on the global level, allocative efficiency is below the level at which it could eventually be. The same could happen with foreign customers' and consumers' wel- fare and overall allocative efficiency in case 2 above, regardless of the le- gality of the undertaking's action and its effects. In a case where there is found an obvious breach of competition law which would at the end result in being obviously worse off, the case raises no concern. Such an undertaking!0 would be found guilty for breaching competition law. But what if the foreign undertaking is behaving in conformity with compe- tition law and at the same time there exists a risk that other producers within the importing country would run out of business?n If it even- tually happens that competent authorities of the importing state, as a reaction to such a situation, take antidumping measures or either limit or completely prohibit the import of such goods or services and so caus- ing customers and consumers to be worse off, this kind of practice is, in our opinion, not really in conformity with competition law, despite the fact that it could be in conformity with international trade law. We are going to talk about other reasons that require enactment of in- ternational competition rules in the next chapter,in order to avoid un- necessary repetition of some problems that have to be dealt with to- gether. At this point, we could conclude only that until the time when we would not have uniform global competition rules, we could not talk about global competition, because deciding a competition case with an international element by using or being subjectively influenced by na- tional interests cannot contribute to global allocative efficiency and to global welfare. Apart from this, we should consider that for achieving real global welfare, the efficiency gains should be distributed appropri- ately among the countries despite the continuous willingness of the busi- ness firms to move their production and resources to wherever the costs are lower. 12 How to Deal with a Global Competition Case? PRESENT SITUATION The first thing that the institution in front of which the competition case is pending has to do is to assess under its own private international law whether it has jurisdiction to hear and decide the case (enforcement ju- risdiction). Without going too deep into this issue we can, in general, say that this issue is dealt with either under the incorporation test,n place of conduct test,!4 purpose availment tests15 or, as regards mergers, the threshold test.16 After concluding that it has such a right, the next step is to determine the relevant market. This is nothing more that determining what exactly are the products that compete between them (relevant product market); on which exact territories the undertaking in question is in competition with the other undertaking producing the competitive products (rele- vant territorial market); taking into account that the present situation can reasonably change in a determined period of time, thus making the present anticompetitive behaviour allowed under competition law and vice versa. The test to determine the relevant market can vary from country to country or supranational legal entity 17 and its application is limited to the relevant market located within its territorial jurisdiction. 18 When dealing with a global competition case, the relevant market can extend even beyond national or supranational territorial borders. The case would be e. g. if some countries would promote research and de- velopment in the way that for others it would be hard to determine well in advance the characteristics and time when a new competitive product would enter the market, or capability of the products produced beyond the territorial borders of the present relevant market that could enter it far more easily and far more rapidly (e. g. through information technol- ogy network) than we could consider at the moment when dealing with the case in issue. In addition, there could also be a case when, consider- ing the behaviour of undertakings on their nationally or supranationally territorially limited relevant market, no anticompetitive concern would be caused; but as soon as we take into account their global network and so the ability to jointly offer the customers a completely new, worldwide product (case 5 above), the case could be quite the opposite.19 For such cases, the present approach - by trying to deal with competition cases with an international element by application of national competition laws - is by no mean appropriate. This is another as to argument why the global competition law is needed. After deciding about the jurisdiction issue and determining the rele- vant market, there remains nothing else than application of the substan- tive2° competition law of the forum. What kind of policies competition law can embrace we have already seen earlier in this article. The issue that has raised the most international concerns was that of legal permissibil- ity and legitimacy to enact the law21 to regulate the conduct that occurs wholly outside the territory of the forum but whose effects occur within it. This is the so called problem of extraterritoriality, i. e. extraterritorial application of the national law. The problem was caused by the us court judgment in the Alcoa case22 and it has not yet been solved. We agree that we should not allow the intended conspiracies to cause an anticompetitive effect, or behaviours causing an anticompetitive effect to be safe merely because they were agreed on or managed wholly outside the country of the forum. But on the other hand, there should not be considered just the national interest of the forum where anticompetitive effects occurred, but also the na- tional interests and competition policy of the country of which the un- dertakings in question are nationals,and the national interests and com- petition policy of the country where the action de facto occurred. The cases in which the court, apart from considering the effect, took into account also the intention of the parties, and the national interest of other countries are, for example, the us cases Timberlane,23 Uranium cartel,24 and Hartford Fire25 - but the main problems still remain. It is hard to imagine that the institution dealing with the case would objec- tively and impartially balance the national interests of the forum and national interests of the other states (Maier 1983, 590-592; Meessen 1984, 788). It is also hard to accept the decision taken in the Hartford fire case that there is no 'true conflict'26 between competition laws, if the com- petition law of one country does not regulate one kind of behaviour or merely allows it (but does not require it) and competition law of the other country explicitly prohibits it, thus allowing for the institution of the forum (i. e. a national competition authority or a court) to decide the case. This is evident interference with the competition policy as a part of the economic policy of another sovereign state, especially if the state chooses the policy neither to order nor to regulate the competition within its territory (Lowe 1981, 265). The same concern would occur if it would be allowed for the under- takings, when concluding the agreement which could raise some anti- competitive issues, to stipulate the submission clause about which state's competition law is going to apply when assessing their behaviour. That is why this kind of contract clause is not permissible. 2y It is evident that each single sovereign state has its own right to decide over its economic policy,28 on the other hand, it can abuse such a right for pursuing aims that are clearly in breach of competition law and the policy of other sovereign states without facing any legal consequences. This can happen either if a state acts in its own authoritative power29 or if it enacts a law that compels private parties to behave in an exactly determined way30, thus causing the anticompetitive effects within others' national or supranational territorial borders. WHAT SHOULD BE DONE IN/FOR THE FUTURE? We have seen above that determination of competition policy and its im- plementation through enacting the competition laws and enforcing them is within the complete power of each sovereign state. This means that there are states that have not yet enacted their competition law statutes, states that have enacted them but their substance is quite the opposite or else interferes with the competition policy of other states, and there are states whose competition law and policy is in conformity with the com- petition law and policy of other states. For this assessment, comparing merely the letters of the articles or decisive sentences in the judgments or administrative decisions is not enough. What should be done is to compare the real values and national interests that crucially dictate the final solution of the case. Only at the point when these kinds of values and national interests are going to be shared all around the World are we going to be able to say that we have legitimate, uniform and completely effective global competition law. At least for the present^1 it is irrational to expect that such common values and national interests are going to be shared all around the World. Requiring that the undertakings from the poor and undeveloped coun- tries should respect the same rules when acting and competing with un- dertakings from developed countries, without at the same time consid- ering also the socio-cultural differences and environmental protection (see Jones and Surfin 2001,1073; Bushman 1980,253,255-56),is something that really cannot be seen as fair especially if, with such an expectation, we hinder the economic progress within those countries. But this does not mean that there is nothing that could be done towards fostering the progress towards global competition law. Under oecd recommendations^ some countries with almost the same level of development and quite common sharing of the competi- tion policy values have concluded bilateral agreements for cooperation and coordination in dealing with global antitrust cases. Personally, we do not believe that global competition law can be regulated in such a way. Mergers like Boeing/McDonnell Douglas or Gencor/Lornor can clearly show that despite such agreements there are always national interests af- fected in the concrete case (Peck 1998,1169) to dictate the final solution. Apart from this, such an agreement can hardly be fully invoked in front of judicial authorities because it is always in the hands of the court to decide if acting in conformity with all the provisions of such an agree- ment is allowed under national or supranational law. There could be, for example, a different level of protection of privacy and/or important commercial information that would not allow for institutions having the jurisdiction to hear the case to exchange such information. This was evident also in the Microsoft case. The only real positive contribution towards global competition law that could be found in such bilateral agreements is the positive comity provision, under which the affected state is obliged33 to ask the affecting state to take the action against its undertaking causing anticompetitive damages in the territory of the af- fected state before the latter is allowed to start enforcement under its own national law. A completely separate question is that of how to solve international merger (case 4 above) when it is allowed under the national law of one country, but not under the national law of the other. Deciding on the merit, international merger should not be distinguished radically from other global competition cases, but there is one thing that could be done to avoid these contestable decisions. By harmonising the thresholds that confer jurisdiction in interna- tional merger cases it would no longer be possible that conflicts of juris- diction could arise. To achieve this, states should first of all (Fiebig 2000, 242) diminish their hegemony and reduce their budget monetary funds dedicated to dealing with so many (some of them not even important) international mergers. The only solution that could properly deal with global competition cases is by setting up a new, completely autonomous international court for global competition cases. Embodied with the power to decide not only on hard-core anticompetitive practices but on all kind of activi- ties performed by either states or private entities which can raise com- petition concerns and by considering some private international law issues,34 considering objectively and impartially various national inter- ests involved in each single case without forgetting to pursue the aim of moving towards uniform global competition law that is necessary if we wish to achieve the real international - global - trade and worldwide welfare. A Step away from the World Trade Organization Someone could legitimately pose the question of why we need to set up a completely autonomous international court for global competition cases if we can take advantage of the already established dispute settlement body within wTo (Mitchell 2001, 358) - some of its agreements already covering competition matters (Mitchell 2001, 359-61; Matsushita 2004, 364) - and what counts the most, to deal jointly - within the same case - with both, trade and competition issues? By regulating competition policy within the framework of the wto and at the same time modifying the existing wto settlement rules that would allow35 also36 private parties to bring the claim, both against the wto member states and other private parties, we could obtain the com- plete trade liberalization, with fully opened markets, fair and equal busi- ness opportunities for every participant in the market, transparency and fairness in the regulatory process, the promotion of efficiency, and the maximization of consumer welfare37. It is more than evident that, merely under the existing set of the wto rules, such an aim cannot be achieved. Within the ambit of purely pro- tectionist rules38, where the looking on the global trade is from each sin- gle national market perspective (Drexel 2004, 446) and where govern- ments are allowed to undertake countervailing measures for protecting domestic industries regardless of the fact that in such a way they may trade off the economic well-being of their people, there is no room for effectiveness and distribution of welfare. The case is even more serious as there exists the real and lawfully supported39 opportunity for the private restraints of international trade. Whether there is any worth in having such an international legal sys- tem, in which the prohibition of governments' obstacles to the interna- tional trade could not be circumvented by private parties' practices, is an issue beyond the scope of this article; what does count, however is that this problem was made evident, and not only at the wto Singapore Ministerial Conference in 1996 - when the wto Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition policy was established - but also in distant 1948 when the Draft fundamental document for the Inter- national Trade Organization (Havana Charted) was written. The attempt to regulate competition policy within the wto finally failed at the Ministerial Conference in Cancun in 2003, when develop- ing countries did not accept the proposal (prepared by wto Working Group on the Interaction between Trade and Competition policy - and mostly forced by eu Countries) to set up competition law rules within their national territories considering minimal standards agreed at inter- national level. There is no necessity for deep analysis of the real reasons4i for the Cancun failure, but what was even more than evident was the fact that by accepting the wto Working Group proposal, the develop- ing countries would give away the advantages of special and differential treatment that they had been enjoying till then under the wto rules.42 Three points to consider are: that there really exists a huge gap be- tween the levels of the economic situation, competition regimes, legal tradition, and cultural context among various states; that there have to be considered various national interests in deciding a specific global com- petition case; that there are products or national resources that raise the global competition problems without having anything to do with trade43. Therefore, from our point of view, the most efficient way to deal with the global competition issues, is by setting up an autonomous in- ternational institution which would consider in every single case all the relevant (national) interests, objectively and impartially balancing them, taking into account the positions, rights and duties conferred on the par- ties by bilateral and multilateral international treaties and, of course, al- ways having in mind the main purpose of promoting, achieving, and protecting global competition and ensuring appropriate and fair distri- bution of welfare among consumers of various parts of the world. Some Procedural Problems in Enforcing a Competition Case Everyone would agree that it would be worthless to have properly bal- anced competition law that mirrors the competition policy perfectly without being able to enforce it. As we have seen above, until the time when there would be an international institution that would have the power to primarily deal with global competition issues there would be national courts and national competition authorities dealing with such cases. Being a competitor acting not only within national borders but also within the territories of other states44 or being merely a consumer, who was a trade-off of the benefits that would otherwise occur in the case of fair competition, you should be aware which authority can decide on competition issues, for what purposes the authority is dealing with the case, who has a right to start and conduct the procedure till the final decision on the case is taken, who has to provide the evidence of anti- competitive harm, and who pays the costs of procedure.^ We are not going to discuss all those issues in depth, but what everyone should know is that, if you wish to obtain damages for anticompetitive harm you have occurred, it is up to you to start the civil procedure in front of the court that has the right, under the private international law of the forum, to hear the case and to provide all the evidence necessary to prove your allegations. Considering that national legal systems differ among one another, that each of them has its own rationale, each of them mirrors its tradition, culture, state of development business firms and their advisors and so must learn to keep abreast of a multitude of legal systems. That such diversity in legal systems, and so in legal standards, increases the costs of doing business^ around the World is not hard to realize. In addition to all these concerns, we should not be surprised if, from time to time, we find ourselves, when presenting the case, in the position when it would be legally not possible to obtain the evidence or sensitive data located within the jurisdiction outside the forum, or when we could be deprived from full enforcement of the final judgment, which could be the case if the defendant did not have any assets within the jurisdic- tion of the forum. Additional obstacles to full enforcement of our rights could derive from so-called blocking statutes enacted by other states to protect their citizens from extraterritorial enforcement of other states' competition law.47 Conclusion It is not yet possible to speak about global competition law. Deal- ing with the competition cases having international element there are (supra)national competition authorities or (supra)national courts, de- ciding on jurisdiction and merit by applying their own laws and giving a partial priority to their national interests (Fox 2003, 923-24; Soma and Wiengarten 2000, 42; Fiebig 2000, 234-37). Objective and impartial dealing with such international cases would be possible only by having a completely autonomous international court for global competition cases that could contribute to the expansion of those kinds of values and interests that would enable global competition law to be formed and enforced all around the World, and so making international trade fully beneficial for our common welfare. Notes 1 About the changes in global economy see also Fox 1995, 8. 2 That is, in the sense of having a core of international - global - com- petition rules that would be binding all around the world. 3 See DiLorenzo n. d., 6. 4 Competition law has potent historical, economic, political, and so- cial roots that make it a market nation's ultimate forum of public law. Short of reading a written constitution, a nation's competition law will tell you the most about its economic and political system and whether it puts its faith in the commands of the government or the operation of the market (Waller 1997, 395). 5 At this point, we intentionally avoid to using the appropriate form of the term jurisdiction in order to avoid confusion with the explanation hereafter. 6 As a legal act through which the state is implementing its competition policy at the concrete behavior. 7 Subject to the positive comity provision in the eventually existing in- ternational bilateral agreement on cooperation in competition mat- ters. Concretely, we are going to discuss this provision hereafter. 8 The eu Commission decision about allowance of export cartels could be found in the Cobelaz case, 6 Nov. 1968, jo 1968, l 276/13,19 and 29 (see Bellis 1979, 661). 9 The Ecj case that confirmed as legal such a behavior of national un- dertakings of the eu member states is Javico case (Javico International and the Javico ag v. Yves Saint Laurent Parfums sa (Case c-306/96). For the comparison see Guzman 2000, 6; Tuttle 2003, 322-27. 10 Also when acting through its agents, sub-agents, branches or even through its subsidiaries that which do not have their real autonomy (the Ec Commission case: Dyestaffs case (Aniline Dyes Cartel (1969) cMLR d 23; the ecj Case: ici v. Commission case 48/69, (1972) ecr 619) or by direct, active sales to the purchasers located within import- ing territory (the ecj case: Woodpulps case (Ahlström oy v. Commis- sion Case 89/85, (1988) ecr 1593). 11 Consider the ban the eu posed on the import of Chinese textiles. 12 The same Fox 1995,12 and Drexel 2004, 440. 13 Assessing the place where the undertaking was incorporated, i. e. ei- ther has its seat or board of directors. 14 Here we consider whether the undertaking in question was actively conducting business within the territory above which the institution hearing the case has jurisdiction. 15 The test under which we have to assess whether the undertaking in question has an intention or was aware that its products can enter into the territory above which the institution hearing the case has jurisdic- tion. 16 Legal acts that regulate mergers clearly state in which cases the com- petent institution is going to hear and decide upon merger. 17 For example, within the eu the test used is ssNip and the percentage in price changing that is stated to cause switching of consumers is in the range between 5% and 10%, (see Wish 2001, 27-8). 18 Jurisdiction - right - to hear and decide the case determined by the territory over which this right extends. 19 See Soma and Weingarten 2000, where they present such a multina- tional network effect on the case of Broadcast-Media and News cor- poration. 20 Some of the procedural law issues will be analyzed more closely in the chapter of this article. 21 So called prescriptive jurisdiction, i. e. the right of states to make their laws applicable to persons, territory, or situations (Jones and Surfin 2001,1039; Wish 2001, 392; Maier 1983, 582). 22 United States v. Aluminium Company of America, 148 f. 2nd (Second Circuit, 1945). 23 Timberlane v. Bank of America, 549 f. 2d 597 (9th Circuit) 1976 and Timberlane v. Bank of America, 749 f . 2d 1378 (9th Circuit) 1984. 24 In Re Westinghouse Uranium, 563 f. 2d 992 (10th Circuit) 1977 and In Re Uranium Antitrust Litigation, 617 f. 2d 1248 (Seventh Circuit) 1980. 25 Hartford Fire Insurance Co. v. California 113 s Ct 2891 (1993), 61 us Law Week 4855. 26 Which only would require, under the principle of international comity, the necessary balancing of national interests that would be harmed by application of the law of the forum on the foreigners' conduct oc- curred abroad. 27 People who live within a national territory have the right to decide on the basis of the self determination about the public order that would be in force within this territory and so about the economic policy that makes part of it. As a consequence, state lacks the power to enforce the foreign competition policy as part of a wider foreign economic policy. (See Lowe 1984, 519, 522, 524-525; Rosen 1981, 217, 222; Lowe 1981, 277.) 28 It derives from the right of the citizens to decide about the conditions and the quality of the life they wish to live as a politically and legally organized society within clearly determined territorial borders. About the rule of noninterference in the field of competition, see Meessen 1984, 804. 29 This case is regulated by the Act of State doctrine. For example, the countries, members of the opec can decide about exploitation of their national resources without being under supervision of any other supranational or international organization that would be able to as- sess on the merit the opec's decisions with regard to the anticompet- itive effects such decisions can cause (see Sornarajah 1982,142-143). 30 In this case private parties could rely on the so-called compulsion de- fense (see Jones and Surfin 2001,1043; Sornarajah 1982,144; Bellis 1979, 677). 31 As is evidenced also in unacceptance of the International Antitrust Code, prepared by the so-called Munich group. 32 About them see Waller 1997, 361-62. 33 This is not the case when the affecting country has no jurisdiction to hear the case or it is not prepared to deal actively with the case, or not expeditiously enough (see Jones and Surfin 2001,169). 34 In the same way as the ecj ruled about understanding of the Rome convention on the Law Applicable to Contractual Obligations, these being a consequence of the diversity of law of contracts and torts among various member states. 35 Under the present regulation, this is not possible, except for cases of dumping, state trade monopolies and companies enjoying exclusive or special privileges (Castrillon 2001,101). See also Matsushita 2004, 370; Fox 1995, 9. 36 The wto rules seek to supervise government restriction on trade (Charnovitz 2003, 829). 37 This is the key concept common to both, the wto and competition policy (Matsushita 2004, 364). 38 See Mitchell 2001, 363, Griffin 1997, 40. 39 At least not prohibited (see the footnote 35). 40 See Fox 1995, 2-3. 41 For them see Stewart 2004; Drexel 2004, 435-37. 42 Consider Nottage 2003, 33-34, 44, where he also stressed the problem of capability and costs that the developing countries would incur in setting up the efficient competition law system. 43 In this regard see also Leon 1997,164,175 and Griffin 1997, 39. 44 The physical presence within the territory is completely irrelevant. What count are the results and effects of your activity. 45 For the reasons why private enforcement of the competition law in the us is much more frequent than in the eu see Baundenbacher 2002, 365. 46 About this, see also Fox 1995,14. 47 About the British blocking statute see Jones and Surfin 2001, 1045, Wish 2001, 393 and, 407, Rosen 1981, Bushman 1980, Lowe 1981. References Baudenbacher, C. 2002. Judicialization of European competition policy. In International antitrust law & policy, ed. B. E. Hawk, 353-9. New York: Fordham Comparative Law Institute. Bellis, J. F. 1979. International trade and the competition law of the Euro- pean economic community. Common Market Law Review 16:647-83. Bushman, K. 1980: The British protection of Trading Interests Act of 1980: An analysis. The Journal of International Law and Economics 14:253-80. Castrillon, C. O. G. 2001. Private parties under the present wTo (bilater- alist) competition regime. Journal of World Trade 35 (1): 99-122. Charnovitz, S. 2003. The World Trade Organization and law enforcement. Journal of World Trade 37 (5): 817-37. DiLorenzo, T. J. N. d. The antitrust economists' paradox. Http://www .mises.org/journals/scholar/DiLorenzo.pdf. Drexel, J. 2004. International competition policy after Cancun: Placing a Singapore issue on the wTo development agenda. World Competition 27 (3): 419-57. Fiebig, A. 2000: A role for the wTo in international merger control. North- western Journal of International Law and Business 20:233-54. Fox, E. M. 1995. Competition law and the agenda for the wTo: Forging the links of competition and trade. Pacific Rim Law & Policy Journal 4 (1): 1-36. -. 2003. International antitrust and the Doha Dome. Virginia Jour- nal ofInternational Law 43:911-32. Guzman, A. T. 2000. International antitrust and the wTo: The lesson from intellectual property. Working Paper Series 36, University of Califor- nia. Griffin, J. P. 1997. The wto study of the interaction between trade and competition policy: Timely and controversial. International Trade & Regulation 3 (2): 39-41. Jones, A., and B. Surfin. 2001. ec competition law: Text, cases, and materi- als. New York: Oxford University Press Leon, I. D. 1997. The dilemma of regulating international competition un- der the wto system. European Competition Law Review 18 (3): 162-77. Lowe, A. V. 1981. Blocking extraterritorial jurisdiction: The British protec- tion of Trading Interests Act, 1980. The American Journal of Interna- tional Law 75:257-82. -. 1984. Public international law and the conflict of laws: The Euro- pean response to The United States export administration regulations. International and Comparative Law Quarterly 33:515-30. Maier, H. G. 1983. Interest balancing and extraterritorial jurisdiction. The American Journal ofComparative Law 31:579-97. Matsushita, M. 2003. Basic principles of the wto and the role of competi- tion policy. Washington University Global Studies Law Review 3:363-85. Meessen, K. M. 1984. Antitrust jurisdiction under customary international law. The American Journal of International Law 78:783-810. Mitchell, A. D. 2001. Broadening the vision of trade liberalisation, interna- tional competition law and the wto. World Competition 24 (3): 343-65. Nottage, H. 2003. Trade and competition in the wto: Pondering the ap- plicability of special and differential treatment. Journal of International Economic Law 6 (1): 23-47. Peck, B. 1998. Extraterritorial application of antitrust laws and the us-eu dispute over Boeing and McDonnell Douglas merger: From comity to conflict? An argument for binding International agreement on an- titrust enforcement and dispute resolution. San Diego Law Review 25:1163-214. Rosen, P. J. 1981. The protection of Trading Interests Act. The International Lawyer 15:213-32. Soma, J. T., and E. K. Weingarten. 2000. Multinational economic network effects and the need for an international antitrust response from the World Trade Organization: A case study in Broadcast-Media and News Corporation. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Eco- nomic Law 21:41-129. Sornarajah, M. 1982. The extraterritorial enforcement of us antitrust laws: Conflict and compromise. International and Comparative Law Quar- terly 31:127-49. Stewart, T. 2004. The fate of competition policy in Cancun: Politics or substance? Legal Issues of Economic Integration 31 (1): 7-11. Tuttle, W. J. 2003. The return of Timberlane? The Fifth Circuit signals a re- turn to restrictive notions of extraterritorial antitrust. Vanderbilt Jour- nal of Transnational Law 36:319-66. Waller, S. W. 1997. The internationalization of antitrust enforcement. Boston University Law Review 77:343-404. Wish, R. 2001. Competition law. 4th ed. London: Butterworths.